Table 1 Details of model’s parameters.
Parameters | Definitions | Value range | References |
---|---|---|---|
k | Local government A’s RIIL ratio coefficient. | 0 < k < 1 | (M Zhang et al., 2019) |
m | When the local government A is unwilling to cooperate, it can complete the ratio coefficient of RIIL. | 0 < m < 1 | (Heberer, Trappel (2013)) |
Bl | Potential benefits to local governments if RIIL is completed (ecosystem service value). | Bl ≥ 0 | |
Ca | Cost of local government A’s RIIL (engineering costs, compensation payments, and potential costs). | Ca ≥ 0 | (F Wu, 2022) |
Cb | Cost of local government B’s RIIL (engineering costs, compensation payments, and potential costs). | Cb ≥ 0 | (F Wu, 2022) |
Fa | Local government A can obtain financial special funds from the superior government through RIIL. | Fa ≥ 0 | (Z Jiang et al., 2023) |
Fb | Local government B can obtain financial special funds from the superior government through RIIL. | Fb ≥ 0 | (Z Jiang et al., 2023) |
Qs | Benefits to superior government from RIIL (urban construction land quotas). | Qs > 0 | (Z Zhang et al., 2019) |
r | The reputation loss of superior government. | r > 0 | (M Zhang et al., 2019) |
c | The administrative cost of superior government. | c > 0 | (M Zhang et al., 2019) |
p | The penalty for non-cooperative local government behaviors, including shirking responsibility and delaying the implementation of projects. | p > 0 | (M Zhang et al., 2019) |