Abstract
Driven by government-led digital transformation initiatives and the rapid development of blockchain technology, low-carbon supply chain management is increasingly confronted with the dual imperative of investing in low-carbon technologies while effectively integrating blockchain systems to maximise corporate profits. This study examines low-carbon product supply chains by assessing the impact of government subsidy policies on manufacturers’ investment decisions in low-carbon technology, particularly in the context of blockchain adoption. Using a game-theoretic framework, four distinct supply chain models are developed to reflect scenarios with and without blockchain adoption and to compare the effects of technology-oriented and output-based subsidy policies. The findings suggest that larger subsidies encourage greater investment in low-carbon technologies, with higher total subsidy amounts having a stronger incentive effect. Notably, in the absence of blockchain technology, technology subsidy policies result in higher product pricing. However, when blockchain is introduced, manufacturers strategically increase wholesale prices to capture a greater share of the subsidy benefits, with the extent of the price adjustment depending on the subsidy amount. To effectively stimulate consumer purchases, policymakers should carefully consider the implications of implementing technology subsidies in markets lacking blockchain infrastructure. In addition, strengthening consumer trust in green products motivates manufacturers to intensify their efforts to reduce emissions, leading to higher wholesale and retail prices without dampening demand. These findings highlight the crucial roles of both subsidy mechanisms and blockchain technology in developing efficient low-carbon supply chain strategies. This study also introduces a unified analytical framework that defines the boundaries of low-carbon technology investments across various policy and technological scenarios, offering valuable insights for policymakers, industry stakeholders, and researchers.
Similar content being viewed by others
Introduction
Governments worldwide are actively promoting low-carbon (LC) transitions across various industries to improve global climate governance. This phenomenon encourages enterprises to invest in low-carbon technology (LCT), which can effectively reduce greenhouse gas emissions in sectors such as electricity, transportation, construction, renewable energy, clean coal utilisation, oil and gas, coalbed methane development, and carbon capture and storage. Its application not only improves energy efficiency and reduces carbon emissions but also promotes the sustainable development of the supply chain (SC). Transitioning to LC practices is critical not only for achieving global emission reduction targets but also for fostering sustainable economic growth and facilitating a green recovery. However, investing in LCT often increases overall enterprise costs, posing significant financial challenges during the adoption phase. To mitigate these challenges, government subsidy policies (SPs) are necessary to guide enterprises in LCT investments. In practice, governments generally implement two primary forms of subsidy policies: technology subsidy policies (TSPs) and output subsidy policies (OSPs). TSPs provide direct financial support for research and development (R&D) activities and the procurement of equipment, thereby easing upfront capital burdens. For instance, the Jing’an District Government in Shanghai offers a 30% subsidy for investments in independent energy-saving renovation projects (Jing’an District Government, 2024). In contrast, OSPs offer financial rewards based on the actual output of LC products or verified emission reductions, thereby incentivising performance-based results. A notable example is the policy implemented by the Fanchang District Government in Wuhu, Anhui Province, which provides a subsidy of 0.05 yuan per kilowatt-hour for self-consumed distributed photovoltaic energy exceeding 500 kilowatt-hours (Fanchang District Government, 2022). The two policies differ significantly in timing and incentive mechanisms. TSPs act as ex-ante incentives by subsidising initial input costs, thereby encouraging investment in LCT R&D, whereas OSPs function as ex-post rewards, indirectly promoting the application of LCT by providing subsidies based on the output of LC products.
Furthermore, blockchain technology (BT), an important digital technology, is gradually becoming a powerful tool for advancing low-carbon supply chains (LCSCs). For example, China Huadian Corporation has developed a digital carbon emission management system based on BT to facilitate enterprises’ green and LC transformation (ChinaHuadian Corporation, 2023). With its decentralised, transparent and tamper-proof data-sharing capabilities, blockchain enhances the traceability of carbon emissions data and reduces information asymmetry in SCs (Ji et al., 2022), thereby effectively strengthening consumer trust in green products (Babich and Hilary, 2020). Moreover, blockchain can help enterprises reduce production costs by improving production efficiency, which in turn significantly influences corporate decision-making (Niu et al., 2021; Xu et al., 2021). Although BT offers theoretical potential for enhancing LC governance, its practical application remains limited because of uncertainties about its economic viability and misalignment between policy incentives and corporate decision-making. Existing research has primarily examined blockchain’s applications in carbon footprint tracking and emissions trading. However, its influence on LCT investment decisions under different government SPs has received relatively little systematic exploration. Furthermore, many previous studies assume that government subsidies uniformly promote LC investments, often neglecting the complex relationship between subsidy effectiveness, the extent of blockchain integration, and levels of consumer trust. It is worth noting that consumer trust in enterprise product information, including carbon reduction data, is an important consideration (Li et al., 2023). If this issue is not effectively addressed, enterprises’ motivation for LC investments may be weakened. BT can also accurately reflect enterprises’ actual carbon emission data, enabling consumers to obtain carbon emission information. In summary, through structural and technological optimisation, BT has significant potential to reduce its energy consumption, improve traceability efficiency, and promote both carbon reduction and efficiency improvement. Given the potential advantages of LC governance, some governments have begun to develop public blockchain platforms to record and share real-time carbon emission data across SCs. For example, the Zhejiang Provincial Government in China has established a province-level integrated management platform based on BT, providing carbon and emission rights management services for over 1,600 enterprises, with an expected management coverage of over 200 million tonnes of carbon emissions (DOIT, 2024).
Although TSPs have been widely implemented in practice, the existing literature reveals a significant research gap regarding OSPs. This study addresses this gap by systematically comparing how these two distinct incentive mechanisms (TSPs and OSPs) influence corporate investment decisions in LCT. Simultaneously, the lack of transparency regarding crucial product information often makes it difficult for consumers to verify the genuine environmental benefits of green products during purchase, consequently undermining market valuation and purchase intentions (Xu and Duan, 2022). To address this information asymmetry, the study incorporates BT, leveraging its decentralised, transparent, and tamper-resistant features to strengthen consumer trust in green products, thereby further incentivising firms to invest in LCT. Notably, different SPs may have varying effects on multiple dimensions, including corporate blockchain adoption, LC investment strategies, product pricing, and overall SC decarbonisation performance. Given global efforts to accelerate LC transitions for greenhouse gas reduction, integrating BT with alternative SPs within a unified analytical framework not only contributes to theoretical innovation but also offers practical insights for effective policymaking and strategic corporate planning.
Based on the aforementioned research, this study focuses on the following three key questions:
-
(1)
How do government SPs influence enterprises’ LCT investment decisions within SCs?
-
(2)
Which type of SP is more effective in promoting enterprises’ LCT investments?
-
(3)
Does the level of green trust influence enterprises’ pricing decisions?
To address these questions, this study constructs a Stackelberg game model within an LC product SC consisting of a manufacturer and retailer while considering the presence of a government blockchain platform, and incorporates two policy scenarios: TSP and OSP. This analytical framework systematically reveals the manufacturer’s optimal decision-making regarding blockchain adoption and LCT investment under different SPs and further examines how these decisions affect product pricing, consumer demand, and overall SC carbon emissions. By comparing equilibrium results under different combinations of blockchain adoption and SPs, this study identifies the impact of TSP and OSP on LCT investment under blockchain-enabled information disclosure.
This study presents three key innovations and contributions. First, it develops a unified analytical model based on a Stackelberg game-theoretic framework that integrates blockchain adoption with differentiated government SPs. This novel methodological approach incorporates dynamic consumer factors, such as green trust, into strategic interactions between manufacturers and retailers, thereby advancing the understanding of the intersection between BT and LC investment decisions. The proposed framework defines the boundary conditions for LCT investments under both TSP and OSP. Theoretically, this study makes two significant contributions: (1) it reveals the distinct effects of ex-ante (TSP) and ex-post (OSP) subsidy mechanisms on corporate investment behaviour, and (2) it demonstrates how blockchain-enhanced transparency mitigates information asymmetries while highlighting the crucial role of green trust in shaping consumer demand for LC products. From a practical perspective, the findings yield actionable insights for both firms and policymakers. For businesses, the strategic implementation of blockchain can enhance the credibility of emissions data, enabling more effective pricing, production planning, and SC coordination to achieve both cost efficiency and emission reduction. For policymakers, the study recommends adopting flexible subsidy strategies (TSP/OSP) tailored to specific industry characteristics and reinforcing them with blockchain-enabled carbon tracking systems to enhance policy transparency and effectiveness. Importantly, the costs associated with blockchain implementation should be carefully managed to maximise its positive impact on LC investment incentives.
Literature review
The research on LCSC is extensive: it focuses on three aspects closely related to the objectives of this study.
LCT investment
Research on LCT investment has established a multidimensional analytical framework encompassing policy instrument design, market incentive mechanisms, and technology innovation drivers. Existing studies primarily focus on three key areas:
First, in terms of the differential impacts of carbon regulation policies, the incentive effects of carbon tax and carbon trading (CAT) mechanisms on LCT investment exhibit significant heterogeneity. Hasan et al. (2021) demonstrated—through an inventory management model—that carbon tax pricing directly influences corporate profits and emission reduction efficiency. In contrast, the CAT mechanism is more likely to achieve Pareto improvement in SCs (Wang et al., 2024). Lyu et al. (2022) further indicated that enterprises tend to prefer dynamic carbon pricing mechanisms, such as carbon taxes, over rigid carbon quota systems. These findings have been validated in the context of power SCs (Chen et al., 2021) and interregional government competition (Deng et al., 2021), suggesting that policy instruments should be tailored to industry-specific characteristics.
Second, concerning the synergy between market mechanisms and technological innovation, green credit policies (Chen et al., 2022) and carbon emission trading (Liu and Sun, 2021) facilitate LCT innovation by optimising capital allocation. Empirical evidence from China’s pilot CAT system suggests a significant increase in LC patent filings (Zhu and Lee, 2022), while green credit promotes technological upgrading through dual pathways of R&D investment and managerial efficiency (Chen et al., 2022). As an emerging driver, digital transformation enhances firms’ dynamic capabilities through data empowerment, thereby improving LCT innovation efficiency (Yang et al., 2023). Notably, the relationship between LCT investment and firm performance is nonlinear: Li et al. (2021) found that green core competencies serve as a mediating factor, with economies of scale reinforcing this mechanism.
Finally, in terms of policy coordination and systemic transformation challenges, achieving carbon neutrality necessitates the deep coordination of policy portfolios. He et al. (2022) quantitatively analysed China’s 2060 carbon neutrality pathway and indicated that an average annual emission reduction intensity of 9.3% requires significant breakthroughs in both conventional technologies and disruptive innovations. Shang and Lv (2023) conducted a systematic assessment of urban applications of renewable energy technologies, building energy efficiency, and carbon capture technologies, emphasising the necessity of multi-stakeholder governance from a life-cycle perspective. Additionally, international comparative studies have shown that the coordinated design of carbon taxes and subsidies can alleviate corporate transition barriers (Wang et al., 2021), while industrial structural upgrading serves as a critical intermediary for the effectiveness of CAT policies (Liu and Sun, 2021).
Distinct from existing literature, this study integrates the application of BT while examining the impact of government low-carbon SPs (LCSP) on enterprises’ LCT investment decisions.
Enabling and constraining effects of BT
The application of BT in LCSC exhibits a dual characteristic of “transparency enablement” and “energy consumption constraints,” necessitating a cost-benefit tradeoff depending on the specific application context. Existing research primarily focuses on the following three areas:
First, regarding information transparency and SC restructuring, BT enhances the credibility of LC information disclosure and optimises SC decision-making through decentralised ledgers. In the battery recycling sector, BT improves traceability efficiency while reducing carbon emissions (Feng et al., 2024). In the apparel industry, it mitigates information asymmetry related to green efforts through eco-labelling mechanisms (Guo et al., 2020). Within multi-tier SCs, the integration of BT with mixed-integer nonlinear programming (MINLP) models can simultaneously reduce operational costs and carbon emissions (Manupati et al., 2020), whereas a dynamic negotiation mechanism under a Stackelberg game framework facilitates consumer-centric decarbonisation (Hua et al., 2022).
Second, there is an economic and environmental tradeoff associated with BT adoption—while BT enhances social welfare (Xu and Duan, 2022; Zhong et al., 2023; Pun et al., 2021), its high energy consumption may offset its LC benefits. Babaei et al. (2025) argued that the high energy consumption of BT will have a negative environmental impact, advocating for the adoption of wind and solar energy to power blockchain systems. A systematic review by Parmentola et al. (2022) highlighted that BT’s contribution to the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) is highly dependent on application design, necessitating a balance between energy efficiency and transparency.
Finally, BT and LCT exhibit dynamic complementarity in terms of digital-green synergistic innovation pathways within digital SCs. A differential game model by Kang et al. (2024) demonstrated that consumer environmental awareness (CEA) and perceived transparency (CTP) jointly drive firms’ BT adoption and green production investments, achieving optimal economic and environmental benefits via bilateral synergy. Such findings provide novel insights into addressing the “greenwashing” dilemma; however, vigilance is necessary while evaluating the potential for false prosperity among low-tech enterprises (Guo et al., 2024).
The aforementioned studies did not explicitly consider the issue of LC investment. This study integrates BT, differentiated LCSP, and LCT investment to bridge the research gap. Furthermore, our findings reinforce the positive effects of BT in mitigating information asymmetry and enhancing green trust, which aligns with the conclusions drawn in the existing literature.
Blockchain governance mechanisms
Driven by BT, SC governance mechanisms are undergoing a systematic transformation, ranging from contract enforcement to resource allocation. First, smart contract mechanisms have significantly expanded the boundaries of traditional contract management. Dolgui et al. (2020) proposed an event-driven “virtual operation” model, embedding physical operations and information processing within smart contract execution to achieve integrated planning and control. From the perspective of technology adoption, Ameyaw et al. (2023) identified key factors influencing the implementation of smart contracts in multi-party collaborative projects, highlighting their potential to enhance contract enforcement efficiency and trust among stakeholders.
Second, blockchain plays a critical role in supply chain finance (SCF) governance. Natanelov et al. (2022), through Activity-Entity-Data (AED) process mapping, developed a buyer-driven SCF model that reduces credit risk and reconfigures the logic of capital flows. Jiang et al. (2022) developed a blockchain-based trust transmission model via electronic payment vouchers for market-dominant small and medium-sized manufacturing enterprises, alleviating their financing difficulties in SCs and directly demonstrating blockchain’s positive impact on such SCF.
Finally, in terms of decentralised resource allocation and incentive mechanisms, Du et al. (2022) developed a blockchain-based edge computing market model. This model integrates a dual-layer smart contract system with a credibility-driven Proof-of-Stake (PoS) consensus mechanism, achieving efficient matching of resources and tasks. Moreover, the use of Shapley value ensures equitable distribution of returns and mitigates the wealth concentration issues inherent in traditional PoS systems. Alqarni et al. (2023) offered a macro-level review of blockchain’s contribution to SC transparency, fairness, and sustainability, with particular emphasis on its applicability and operational potential in multimodal transport scenarios.
In summary, the existing literature collectively illustrates the evolutionary path of blockchain governance mechanisms across three representative domains: automated contract enforcement, financing optimisation, and resource incentive alignment, offering theoretical foundations for future institutional design and policy development.
Precision design of SPs and collaborative innovation mechanisms
The design of SPs should shift from single-incentive mechanisms toward collaborative innovation frameworks. Existing research has primarily focused on the following three aspects.
First, in terms of the selection and dynamic adjustment of subsidy types, R&D subsidies are more effective than product subsidies in promoting the adoption of electric vehicles (Li et al., 2020), although they need to be complemented by carbon taxes to enhance emission reduction outcomes (Wang et al., 2021). Dynamic R&D subsidies improve innovation quality by increasing marginal effects (Lyu et al., 2024), whereas consumer subsidies, although stimulating demand-side growth, may weaken the overall emission reduction intensity (Bian et al., 2020).
Second, from the perspective of information asymmetry and heterogeneous corporate responses, dual subsidy mechanisms can resolve the incentive mismatch between manufacturers’ emission reduction efforts and retailers’ green promotion strategies (He et al., 2024). Firm size heterogeneity necessitates differentiated policy interventions: large enterprises can leverage digital transformation for LC transitions more effectively (Yang et al., 2023), whereas small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) rely on targeted support through green credit mechanisms (Bai et al., 2021).
Finally, in terms of policy coordination and the enhancement of systemic resilience, the synergy between CAT and green credit can lower entry barriers for cleaner production (Li et al., 2022). Furthermore, BT-enabled transparent subsidy distribution improves policy implementation efficiency (Dong et al., 2023). Notably, subsidies should be integrated with carbon quota allocation mechanisms (Chen et al., 2021) and industrial network embedding strategies (Zhu and Lee, 2022) to foster a risk-resilient innovation ecosystem.
The aforementioned studies, using diverse methodologies and modelling approaches, consistently concluded that SPs facilitate LCT innovation (or investment), which is consistent with the findings of this study. Additionally, by considering differentiated SPs, this study further identifies the boundary conditions under which two types of SP influence firms’ LCT investment incentives.
In summary, existing literature has conducted systematic and in-depth analyses of the impact of SPs on LC investment. However, most studies are grounded in the traditional LCSC perspective. This study introduces BT as a mechanism to address consumers’ lack of trust in firms’ LC product information. Building on this foundation, we examine the influence of SPs on firms’ LCT investment strategies within a blockchain-enabled LCSC, thereby establishing a differentiated research pathway from conventional studies.
Moreover, while prior research has predominantly focused on the factors influencing LCT investment in high-risk and highly uncertain market environments, few studies have explored how LCT investment and blockchain transparency can jointly enhance sustainability within a stable, government-led blockchain platform that provides a reliable data environment. Our study leverages this unique data advantage to propose a more refined analytical framework. Specifically, the stability of blockchain-enabled data significantly enhances consumer trust in firms’ carbon emission reduction records. This, in turn, provides a more reliable informational foundation for firms in developing LCT investment strategies and governments in implementing SPs (Table 1).
Methods
Rationale for selecting game theory
This study investigates an LCSC involving both manufacturers and retailers. As independent economic agents, manufacturers and retailers exhibit both competitive and collaborative behaviour in their pricing decisions. These interactions are also influenced by consumer preferences for LC products and government SPs. Game theory is a well-established tool for analysing strategic interactions between multiple decision-makers. First, game theory captures the strategic decision-making process between manufacturers and retailers, such as how changes in carbon emission reduction (CER) rates and wholesale prices impact retail prices. Second, concepts such as the Nash and Stackelberg Equilibrium provide optimal strategies for each party, allowing for the prediction of equilibrium outcomes under different policy and technological scenarios. Finally, game theory is well-suited for modelling dynamic systems influenced by external factors, such as government SPs and green trust, facilitating a deep analysis of how these factors affect participants’ strategies. In the context of this study, game theory is an ideal framework to explore the strategic interactions of manufacturers and retailers during the adoption and response to BT under the LCSP. These interactions and strategies form the foundation of the analysis in this paper. Therefore, game theory is selected as the methodology for this study. In addition, the research framework is structured to capture core constructs and research variables that influence firms’ decision-making within the LCSC. The primary constructs examined include manufacturers’ and retailers’ pricing strategies, investments in LCT, government SPs (specifically technology and output subsidies), and the role of BT in enhancing information transparency. The key variables analysed include wholesale price, retail price, CER rate, green trust, and subsidy amount. The game-theoretical framework enables a systematic examination of the interactions among these variables and their impact on the equilibrium outcomes, providing a structured approach to evaluating firms’ strategic behaviour under different policy settings.
Rationale for selecting the Stackelberg Game Model
This research presents a typical “leader-follower” hierarchy between manufacturers and retailers: manufacturers determine the wholesale price and CER rate (i.e. investment in LCT). In contrast, retailers adjust the retail price in response to consumer demand. The sequential decision-making characteristic of this process naturally aligns with the Stackelberg game framework. First, the Stackelberg model effectively captures the hierarchical and sequential nature of the decision-making process between upstream and downstream agents. Second, it allows the incorporation of external factors—such as government SPs and consumer LCP—into the decision-making process, facilitating a deeper analysis of their impact on equilibrium outcomes. Ultimately, this model enables scenario analysis to assess the impact of various subsidy schemes (such as TSP or OSP) on SC performance, carbon reduction, and profitability. Therefore, the Stackelberg model was chosen for its suitability to address the specific dynamics of this research.
The construction and solution of the game model in this study are as follows:
-
1.
In the given context, the manufacturer is the leader due to its control over resources and technology, while the retailer acts as the follower.
-
2.
The manufacturer initially determines the LCT investment and wholesale price from the retailer’s potential responses and corresponding optimal strategies.
-
3.
The retailer, following the manufacturer’s decisions, sets the retail price to maximise its profit.
-
4.
Through a series of iterative decisions and adjustments, the manufacturer and retailer reach a Stackelberg equilibrium, where neither can improve their payoff by unilaterally changing their strategy.
In this model, the manufacturer (as the leader) sets both the wholesale price and the CER rate (i.e., the level of LCT investment), while the retailer (as the follower) determines the retail price based on these decisions. This hierarchical decision structure reflects the key characteristics of the Stackelberg model and effectively captures the strategic dynamics between the manufacturer and retailer. The research framework integrates the Stackelberg game model with government SPs and BT adoption. This approach enables an analysis of how subsidy schemes and blockchain transparency affect firms’ decision-making. The primary independent variables within the framework are government subsidy amounts (TSP and OSP), BT adoption costs, and firms’ levels of green trust. The dependent variables include firms’ LCT investment levels, pricing strategies, and overall SC profitability. This structured approach ensures that the model effectively captures the essential interactions among government policies, technological adoption, and corporate strategy within the LCSC. This two-stage model allows for a phased analysis of policies and technologies: in the first stage, the manufacturer makes decisions regarding LCT investment and production based on government SPs and BT adoption costs; in the second stage, the retailer adjusts the retail price based on the manufacturer’s wholesale price, CER rate, and market demand. Through phased analysis, the model provides a clearer understanding of how policy and technological changes impact long-term decision-making. Additionally, the decentralised, transparent, and traceable nature of BT addresses consumers’ trust issues regarding LC product claims. By applying the Stackelberg game model in the context of BT, it becomes possible to analyse how increased information transparency influences the manufacturer’s investment in LCT and production strategies. Specifically, the model provides a framework for solving the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium and predicting the optimal responses of the manufacturer and retailer. Using this model, the optimal subsidy strategy for the government, the optimal LCT investment level for the manufacturer, and the optimal retail price for the retailer can be derived, allowing for an evaluation of the effects of various policies and technologies on corporate strategy.
Perfect information theory
This study assumes that both manufacturers and retailers have full and symmetric access to key information, such as carbon reduction performance, costs, and prices. This assumption is based on the theory of perfect information (Sun et al., 2022), which is a commonly used theoretical foundation in SC game models. However, in practice, LCSC often experiences information gaps, particularly regarding the actual carbon reduction performance and environmental attributes of the products. However, with the application of BT, SCs can achieve real-time, immutable sharing of carbon data, ensuring that all parties in the SC have access to the same information. This improvement in transparency helps bridge the information gap, assuming perfect information is more reasonable in a blockchain-enabled SC environment. Therefore, this assumption is supported not only by economic theory but also by the practical improvements resulting from BT.
Considerations for emerging economies
In the current global economic landscape, emerging economies have evolved as growth engines with robust development momentum. However, the convergence of high-energy-consuming industrial expansion, accelerated industrialisation, and globalisation has led to an exponential increase in carbon dioxide emissions (Rahman et al., 2022). Unlike OECD countries, which are characterised by relatively mature technological progress and a well-established environmental regulatory system, emerging economies face the “green paradox” dilemma under stringent environmental regulations. That is, the tightening of environmental policies may prompt enterprises to accelerate the exploitation of existing resources, thereby exacerbating carbon emissions and constraining sustainable economic development. Nevertheless, these economies possess enormous potential for technological innovation. Research indicates that technological progress can effectively decrease the carbon emission intensity (Wang and Wei, 2020). In particular, investment, R&D and innovation in LCT have become the core pathways for overcoming environmental constraints and achieving LC transitions (Fragkos et al., 2021).
To facilitate LC transitions, governments of emerging economies are actively exploring policy instrument innovations and constructing incentive mechanisms that combine carbon regulation with LC subsidies to guide enterprises in increasing their investment in LCT. However, the uneven development among internal regions poses challenges to the benefit assessment of applying digital technologies such as blockchain in emerging economies. The costs and benefits of technology implementation are difficult to measure accurately. When coupled with regional differences in resource endowments, the effectiveness of policy implementation varies. Nevertheless, as the largest emerging economy in the world, China has achieved significant breakthroughs in integrating the digital economy with LC development. Studies reveal that the digital economy with BT as its underlying architecture can not only directly drive high-quality LC development but also promote collaborative regional transitions through spatial spillover effects (Ma and Zhu, 2022). This practical achievement fully proves that, with scientific planning and policy guidance, BT can serve as an effective tool for emerging economies to overcome the bottlenecks of LC transitions, highlighting the strategic value of digital technologies in sustainable development.
From the micro-perspective of enterprises, influenced by financial constraints and market fluctuations, enterprises in emerging economies exhibit a significant risk-averse tendency in LCT investment, with a greater focus on short-term economic returns. This phenomenon leads to a lower basic adoption rate of LCT compared to enterprises in developed economies. This investment prudence interacts intricately with the policy instruments of emerging economies. In the absence of subsidies, enterprises often view BT as an additional cost burden, as the financial benefits generated by enhanced transparency cannot be realised immediately. However, when subsidies are provided, blockchain adoption becomes more attractive because it enhances the credibility and traceability of emissions reduction, ensuring that enterprises can effectively obtain and maximise government incentives. This dynamic makes the complementary effect between blockchain adoption and LCT investment stronger in emerging economies than in developed markets, where enterprises may already have sufficient resources to invest in LCT independently of subsidy support.
In particular, TSPs and OSPs exert differential impacts on enterprise decision-making. TSPs provide upfront financial support, encouraging enterprises to adopt blockchain as a risk mitigation tool to enhance their eligibility for subsidies. In contrast, OSPs offer rewards after enterprises achieve emissions reductions, which may further incentivise enterprises to adopt blockchain as a verification mechanism to ensure post-investment financial returns. This outcome indicates that the existence and type of subsidies largely determine blockchain’s role in enterprises’ LCT investment decisions. Under TSPs, the influence of blockchain is enhanced, whereas under OSPs, it more heavily depends on actual results.
In conclusion, the intervention of SPs significantly strengthens the correlation between blockchain adoption and LCT investment in emerging economies. The precise design of policy instruments directly affects enterprises’ strategic responses. Future research could further explore the differences in subsidy effectiveness and blockchain adoption rates across different countries, providing theoretical support for emerging economies to formulate more targeted LC transition policies.
Research design and mathematical modelling approach
Given the theoretical modelling approach used in this study, conventional sampling methods and statistical tools were not employed. However, to ensure the rigour of the theoretical framework, the following research design was implemented:
Theoretical foundation
This study is based on established theories of economics and game theory, complemented by relevant literature on SC management and environmental policy.
Construct development
Key constructs, including LCT investment, BT adoption, green trust, and government subsidies, are identified and clearly defined based on a theoretical foundation.
Mathematical modelling
A Stackelberg game framework is used to characterise the hierarchical decision-making process between manufacturers and retailers.
Equilibrium analysis
The model derives the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium using backward induction to ensure optimal decision-making strategies for all participating agents.
Comparative analysis
Different policy scenarios, such as TSPs and OSPs, are comparatively examined to evaluate how different government interventions influence corporate strategies.
Although empirical validation is beyond the scope of this study, the research design ensures that the findings are grounded in robust economic theory and dynamic SC analysis. Future studies may incorporate empirical data to further validate the model’s predictive capacity and enhance its practical relevance.
Discussion of alternative analytical methods
To enhance the credibility of the research methodology and provide a comprehensive understanding of the robustness of the results, this section explores potential alternative analytical methods that could complement the conclusions drawn from the Stackelberg game model.
Aggregate models
Aggregate models are commonly used in macroeconomic analysis and can provide a high-level perspective on LCSCs’ overall performance. For instance, by analysing total carbon emissions, total market demand, and overall profitability, aggregate models can reveal the systemic effects of SPs and blockchain adoption. However, aggregate models are limited in their ability to capture individual strategic interactions between manufacturers and retailers, thus offering limited utility for micro-level decision-making analysis.
Cost-benefit analysis (CBA)
CBA serves as a supplementary tool for evaluating the net economic impact of different SPs and BT implementation scenarios. By quantifying the costs and benefits associated with LCT investments, CBA provides a direct method for assessing the financial feasibility of policy interventions. However, this method is inherently static and does not reflect the dynamic, continuous decision-making processes typical of real-world SC interactions.
Agent-based modelling (ABM)
ABM offers a flexible approach for simulating the behaviours of individual entities (such as manufacturers, retailers, and consumers) within the LCSC. ABM can capture the heterogeneity of agents and the emergent phenomena arising from their interactions. This method can further analyse how consumer preferences, SPs, and BT adoption collectively influence SC dynamics. However, ABM typically requires substantial computational resources and assumptions, which can introduce additional complexity and uncertainty.
System dynamics (SD)
System dynamics focuses on feedback loops and time delays within complex systems and can be used to model the long-term impacts of SPs and BT adoption on the entire SC. For example, SD can assess how changes in green trust, subsidy amounts, and LCT investment propagate throughout the SC. However, similar to aggregate models, SD is not well-suited for capturing individual strategic interactions.
In summary, while alternative methods can offer complementary perspectives, the Stackelberg game model is particularly well-suited for this study due to its ability to model hierarchical interactions, analyse strategic decision-making, and evaluate the impact of policy interventions on LCSC. Furthermore, the existing literature has extensively employed game theory to analyse SPs in LC markets, which further demonstrates its effectiveness in reflecting firms’ strategic behaviours under regulatory constraints.
This study incorporates two commonly used government SPs—TSP and OSP, both of which are widely employed to promote firms’ investments in LCT. By introducing these policy tools within a game-theoretical framework, this research effectively simulates subsidy mechanisms in real-world LC industries. Additionally, the equilibrium analysis results further validate the applicability of the model, as the research findings align with existing empirical studies on the effectiveness of subsidies and the impact of blockchain applications on SC sustainability.
Model assumptions
This study primarily investigates how different LCSPs influence enterprises’ LCT investment strategies in the context of BT. The theoretical model considers the government, manufacturers, retailers, and consumers. First, the critical role of the government was explicitly recognised in the system. The government acts as the builder of the BT application platform, providing technical support and a regulatory framework for economic activities. Second, consumers’ participation is also essential. In the model, we introduce a demand function that includes consumers’ preference for LCP, which directly affects the LC investment strategies of manufacturers and retailers. However, consumers do not directly appear as the subjects of the game; their preferences are an exogenous variable that shapes strategic interactions between manufacturers and retailers. Finally, based on the research purpose and model simplification, manufacturers and retailers are selected as the main players in the game. In SC management, the two players directly determine the investment in LCT and the production of LC products, and their decisions directly affect the adoption and marketing effect of LCT. By focusing on this pair of core players, we can reveal the specific mechanisms and effects of LCSPs more clearly in terms of incentivising LC investments. Therefore, this study examines a secondary SC comprising a manufacturer and retailer. Wang et al. (2020) demonstrated that BT ensures the traceability and transparency of SC information. In this context, we propose that the government invest in the construction of a BT platform, which will then be made available to manufacturers for a fee. Furthermore, the government monitors the information on the blockchain platform to determine whether to subsidise the manufacturer for technology or output investments. Consumers gain access to verified carbon reduction information, which enhances their level of trust in the manufacturer’s green products. The final market demand for LC products is jointly influenced by consumers’ LCP and green trust level. The data used in this study primarily originates from government-led blockchain platforms, which are constructed and funded by local governments and operate in a stable, low-risk environment. Unlike traditional studies in which data uncertainty often arises due to market fluctuations, information asymmetry, and high-risk factors, the data in this study are characterised by high authenticity, traceability, and long-term comparability. This stable data environment provides a solid foundation for constructing the theoretical framework, ensuring that the assumptions of complete information symmetry and low-risk conditions in the model are fully satisfied. The proposed LCSC structure is illustrated in Fig. 1.
The following assumptions were made:
Assumption 1: Market demand is determined by the product’s selling price, CER rate, consumers’ LCP, and consumers’ green trust degree (Li et al., 2021). Research shows that consumers tend to buy LC products (Sun et al., 2020). Green trust is defined as the level of consumer trust in product environmental claims and carbon reduction performance, and it has been extensively studied in the existing literature. Chuah et al. (2020) explored the role of green trust in shaping green brand perception and consumer behaviour. These studies indicate that green trust has a significant impact on consumers’ purchasing decisions in markets where environmental transparency is crucial. When the manufacturer does not apply BT, the green trust coefficient of consumers is 0 < λ < 1, and market demand is q1 due to the opacity of the CER information of the manufacturer’s LC products.
When a manufacturer adopts BT, SC information is relatively transparent and traceable. Then, consumers gain full access to the manufacturer’s carbon reduction information; here, the green trust factor λ = 1. The demand of consumers with LC preference increases due to increased levels of trust, marking a market demand of q2. According to the findings of the “2020 Blockchain Traceability Service Innovation and Application Report”, the implementation of the Jingdong Zhizhen Chain—a blockchain-based anti-counterfeiting and traceability service provided by Jingdong—has significantly boosted brand demand. Notably, the use of BT for the traceability of fresh products resulted in a significant sales increase of up to 77.6%. These results indicate that blockchain-enabled traceability can directly enhance consumer trust in product information, thereby driving an increase in product demand. Based on these insights, the demand expressions for the two cases are formulated as follows:
Assumption 2: Carbon emission is exclusively embodied in the production chain. The manufacturer achieves CER by investing in LCT. The LCT investment cost function \(C(r)=\frac{1}{2}k{r}^{2}\) (Liu et al., 2022), where k is the investment cost coefficient of LCT and r is the CER rate. It is assumed that the LCT investment cost coefficient k satisfies \({\beta }^{2}{\lambda }^{2} < k < {\beta }^{2}\), where β is the consumers’ LC preference coefficient.
Assumption 3: Research has shown that BT can quantify and integrate the contribution of LCT across different sectors. For instance, by employing traceability systems and intelligent optimisation processes, BT can improve material and energy use efficiency while significantly reducing production costs (Deng et al., 2024; Abdelgalil et al., 2021). Accordingly, we assume that when the manufacturer does not apply BT, the manufacturer’s cost of production is z. When manufacturers apply BT, they can integrate LCT into all stages of production through BT, thereby optimising the enterprise’s existing production process, enhancing raw material utilisation and production efficiency, saving labour costs, and collectively reducing total production costs. To reflect the impact of LCT on production efficiency, it is assumed that the production cost of the manufacturer is z − rd, where d is the efficiency coefficient of LCT to reduce costs, and r is the unit CER rate of the product (also representing the level of LCT). Further, d satisfies \(\beta < d < 3\beta\).
Assumption 4: The government’s utility is defined as total social welfare comprising four components: producer surplus, consumer surplus, government fiscal expenditures, and environmental improvements. Producer surplus is the total profit earned by manufacturers and retailers. Consumer surplus is defined as \(\frac{\left(\bar{p}-p\right)q}{2}\), where \(\bar{p}\) is the highest price consumers are willing to pay (i.e., the price when demand for the product is zero), \(\bar{p}=a+\lambda \beta r\). The cost of LC subsidies to manufacturers and the single-cycle shared cost of building the blockchain platform is \(\frac{G}{n}\). Environmental quality improvement is denoted by rq.
Assumption 5: The government has established the BT application platform. For example, the Agriculture and Rural Bureau of Weifang City, Shandong Province, China, developed a BT platform to address issues related to agricultural product traceability, quality and safety, sales links, and the insurance of local agricultural brands (Shandong Big Data Bureau, 2024). This innovation has since been extended across China (iSHANDONG, 2024). Similarly, the BT platform, built by the Georgian government in collaboration with the BitFury Group, was initially applied to land title registration and later extended to other local government departments (PR Newswire, 2017). SC enterprises seeking to use the BT platform are required to pay an application cost exclusively. The unit application cost is denoted as c. This study focuses solely on the application of BT by manufacturers, with the ongoing expenses being determined at the manufacturer’s decision-making stage. The impact coefficient is η. The unit cost of the application is assumed to satisfy \(\frac{{\left(d+\beta \right)}^{2}}{k\left(1-\theta \right)}-4 < c < \frac{4{\left(d+\beta \right)}^{2}}{{\beta }^{2}{\lambda }^{2}}-4\).
Assumption 6: Perfect market information symmetry exists between the manufacturer and retailer. The manufacturer produces LC products that exactly match the market demand, ensuring market clearance. The parameters and their definitions are summarised in Table 2.
Assumption 7: Government-led blockchain platforms ensure the stability and low-risk nature of carbon emissions and LC investment data, such that firms do not need to account for additional risk premiums in their LCT investment decisions, and the incentive effects of government SPs can be accurately quantified.
Model construction and solution
In this section, this study develops a two-stage game model for manufacturers and retailers that involves the application cost of BT, the influence of consumers’ LCP, and the degree of consumers’ green trust. In the first stage, manufacturers aim to maximise their profits by determining the wholesale price w and carbon reduction rate r of LC products. In the second stage, retailers maximise their profits by determining the retail price of LC products p. The equilibrium solutions of models A, B, C, and D are denoted as \({X}^{A* }\), \({X}^{B* }\), \({X}^{C* }\) and \({X}^{D* }\), respectively. These models were applied to the four following scenarios, outlined in Tables 3 and 4.
Model A
In model A, the government provides a subsidy for the manufacturer’s CER investment represented by a TSP factor of θ. The respective profit functions for the government, manufacturer, and retailer are as follows:
In the TSP model, the optimal values for the wholesale price \({w}^{A* }\), carbon reduction rate \({r}^{A* }\), retail price \({p}^{A* }\), demand for LC products \({q}^{A* }\), manufacturer’s profit \({\pi }_{m}^{A* }\), retailer’s profit \({\pi }_{r}^{A* }\), and total social welfare \({\pi }_{g}^{A* }\) can be obtained by solving Eqs. (A3)–(A9), respectively.
Model B
In model B, the government subsidises the output of each unit of the LC product produced by the manufacturer. The subsidy amount is denoted as μ. The respective profit functions of the government, manufacturer, and retailer are as follows:
In the OSP model, the optimal values for the wholesale price \({w}^{B* }\), carbon reduction rate \({r}^{B* }\), retail price \({p}^{B* }\), demand for LC products \({q}^{B* }\), manufacturer’s profit \({\pi }_{m}^{B* }\), retailer’s profit \({\pi }_{r}^{B* }\), and total social welfare \({\pi }_{g}^{B* }\) can be obtained from Eqs. (B3)–(B9), respectively.
Model C
In model C, the government subsidises the manufacturer’s CER investment in proportion to the technology investments, with a TSP coefficient of θ. In addition, the manufacturer must incur a cost to utilise the blockchain platform. Furthermore, applying BT can reduce the manufacturer’s periodical costs. The government must bear both the subsidy for the manufacturer’s technology investment and the cost of constructing the blockchain platform. Therefore, the respective profit functions of the government, manufacturers, and retailers are as follows:
With the application of BT in the TSP model, the optimal wholesale price \({w}^{C* }\), carbon reduction rate \({r}^{C* }\), retail price \({p}^{C* }\), demand for LC products \({q}^{C* }\), manufacturer’s profit \({\pi }_{m}^{C* }\), retailer’s profit \({\pi }_{r}^{C* }\), and total social welfare \({\pi }_{g}^{C* }\) can be determined by Eqs. (C3)–(C9), respectively.
Model D
In model D, the government subsidises the output of each unit of LC product produced by the manufacturer, with the unit subsidy amount denoted as μ. Similarly, the manufacturer pays the cost of using the blockchain platform. Applying BT can reduce the manufacturer’s periodical cost. The government bears both the subsidy for the manufacturer’s technology investment and the cost of constructing the blockchain platform. Therefore, the respective profit functions of the government, manufacturers, and retailers are as follows:
Under the OSP model with the application of BT, the optimal wholesale price \({w}^{D* }\), carbon reduction rate \({r}^{D* }\), retail price \({p}^{D* }\), demand for LC products \({q}^{D* }\), manufacturer’s profit \({\pi }_{m}^{D* }\), retailer’s profit \({\pi }_{r}^{D* }\), and total social welfare \({\pi }_{g}^{D* }\) can be obtained by solving Eqs. (D3)–(D9), respectively.
Model analysis
A unique equilibrium solution exists for the government’s implementation of either the TSP or OSP, depending on whether the manufacturer applies BT. Based on the equilibrium results, we conduct the following analysis: (1) the effects of the CER cost coefficient, LC preference coefficient, and green trust degree on the equilibrium results; (2) a comparative analysis of two SPs in the scenarios where the manufacturer applies or does not apply BT, and a comparative analysis of two SPs when the manufacturer applies BT.
We denote \(M=\left\{A,B\right\}\), and \(N=\left\{A,B,C,D\right\}\). The specific conclusions are summarised below with the proofs provided in the Appendix.
Sensitivity analysis
This section examines the impact of the LCT investment cost coefficient k, LCP coefficient β, and green trust factor λ on the key equilibrium variables, including the CER rate, demand, wholesale price, retail price, and profits of both manufacturers and retailers.
Proposition 1. As the LCT investment cost coefficient k increases, the following expressions are observed: \(\frac{\partial {r}^{N* }}{\partial k} < 0\), \(\frac{\partial {q}^{N* }}{\partial k} < 0\), \(\frac{\partial {p}^{N* }}{\partial k} < 0\), \(\frac{\partial {w}^{N* }}{\partial k} < 0\), \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{m}^{N* }}{\partial k} < 0\), and \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{r}^{N* }}{\partial k} < 0\).
Proposition 1 suggests that irrespective of whether the manufacturer applies BT, increases in the LCT investment cost coefficient k lead to lower CER rates, demand, wholesale price, retail price, and profits for the manufacturer and retailer under both SPs. An increase in this coefficient implies lower LCT investment efficiency, resulting in a weaker CER effect. When retailers observe a decline in the level of product emissions reductions, they are incentivised to lower retail prices to maintain demand. This reduced demand influences the SC and the consumer end, prompting manufacturers to lower wholesale prices due to concerns regarding unsold inventories. This reduced demand is the primary factor driving lower retailer profits, whereas lower demand, lower wholesale prices, and higher LCT investment costs contribute to lower manufacturer profits.
These findings suggest that reducing the cost coefficient of LCT investments or improving its efficiency is conducive to improving the LC level of products. In practice, technology accounts for 30% of the overall determinants of the enterprise’s emission reduction effect (Song et al., 2023). Thus, enterprises should be incentivised to research, develop, and improve LCT to increase efficiency and hence benefit from emission reduction. Technological advances and scale effects reduce the cost of emission reduction and increase investment in renewable energy. For example, as reported by the International Renewable Energy Agency (IRENA), due to the overall advancement of renewable energy technology, by the end of 2022, global renewable energy capacity reached 3,372 GW, representing an increase of 9.6% year-on-year, with solar power capacity increasing by 22% (191 GW) (EP, 2023).
Proposition 2. As the LC preference coefficient β increases, the following expressions are observed: \(\frac{\partial {r}^{N* }}{\partial \beta } > 0\), \(\frac{\partial {q}^{N* }}{\partial \beta } > 0\), \(\frac{\partial {p}^{N* }}{\partial \beta } > 0\), \(\frac{\partial {w}^{N* }}{\partial \beta } > 0\), \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{m}^{N* }}{\partial \beta } > 0\), \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{r}^{N* }}{\partial \beta } > 0\).
Proposition 2 suggests that the increasing consumer preference for LC products leads to higher CER rates, demand, wholesale prices, retail prices, and profits for manufacturers and retailers under both SPs, regardless of whether the manufacturer applies BT. An increase in the LC preference coefficient β enhances consumer sensitivity to LC products, incentivising more investment in LCT as higher market demand creates a more favourable return on investment. In turn, the increased demand stimulates enterprises’ willingness to invest in LCT, leading to the cyclical nature of LCSC. In addition, a higher consumer preference for LC products enables firms to increase product prices, as SC firms often pass on some of their LCT investment costs to consumers.
These findings demonstrate that maintaining a high preference for LC products can lead to increased investments in LCT and higher profits. Simultaneously, firms increase the pricing of preferred LC products, reflecting the commercial value of carbon reduction. In addition to advertising and other publicity measures, the government can implement a reward mechanism that cultivates consumers’ LC behaviour awareness. For example, a collaborative platform developed by Tencent and the Shenzhen Municipal Bureau of Ecological Environment, along with other institutions, has created a system that qualifies and rewards positive carbon behaviour by constructing a set of citizens’ CER mechanisms (CNR News, 2022). This mechanism, with characteristics of “recordable, measurable, profitable, and recognised”, establishes a positive feedback loop that combines commercial incentives and policy encouragement. Such incentives can help nurture a growing base of consumers with strong LC preferences, which, in turn, will contribute to the expansion of the LC product market.
Proposition 3. As the green trust factor λ increases, the following effects are observed: \(\frac{\partial {r}^{M* }}{\partial \lambda } > 0\), \(\frac{\partial {q}^{M* }}{\partial \lambda } > 0\), \(\frac{\partial {p}^{M* }}{\partial \lambda } > 0\), \(\frac{\partial {w}^{M* }}{\partial \lambda } > 0\), \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{m}^{M* }}{\partial \lambda } > 0\), and \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{r}^{M* }}{\partial \lambda } > 0\).
Proposition 3 reveals that an increase in the green trust λ leads to higher carbon reduction rates, demand, wholesale price, retail price, and profits for manufacturers and retailers, especially when BT is not applied, under both SPs. An increase in green trust indicates that consumers have greater confidence in the manufacturers’ LC claims, whether through blockchain disclosure or marketing efforts. This trust incentivises firms with low emission reduction levels to invest in LCT more aggressively, knowing that consumers will respond positively. The main factors influencing demand in this context are green trust levels and emission reductions. As green trust increases, more consumers with LC preferences tend to break down information barriers and buy the manufacturer’s products, driving up demand. This, in turn, prompts manufacturers to increase wholesale prices and retailers to adjust their retail prices accordingly. Ultimately, the profits of all SC members will increase.
These results suggest that fostering green trust can significantly enhance the manufacturer’s incentive to reduce emissions and invest in LCT when BT has not been applied. In the absence of BT, governments can foster consumer trust in LCT and green products through certification systems and public awareness campaigns. For instance, the “Energy Star” programme, jointly launched by the U.S. The Department of Energy (DOE) and the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) enhance consumer confidence in energy-efficient products via their labelling system. By incentivising firms to redesign products and adopt advanced technologies to meet energy efficiency standards, the programme awards the Blue Energy Star label to the top 25% of the most energy-efficient products (GBA, 2017). This boost in green trust not only drives LCT investments but also increases firm profitability through enhanced market competitiveness. Additionally, a high level of green trust allows manufacturers to better transfer the cost of investment in LCT to consumers, thereby facilitating the development of the LC market.
Comparative analysis
In this section, propositions 4 to 7 compare the equilibrium solutions of the two SPs when BT is not applied, while propositions 8 to 11 perform the same comparison when BT is applied.
Proposition 4. When comparing the equilibrium CER rate under the TSP and OSP when the BT is not applied, the following can be observed: when \(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{1}\), \({r}^{A* } > {r}^{B* }\); when \(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{1}\), \({r}^{B* } > {r}^{A* }\) (as shown in Fig. 2).
The results show that TSP is more effective for increasing the CER rate of enterprises when the unit subsidy for manufacturers is small (\(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{1}\)). Under such conditions, OSP yields a lower total subsidy for the manufacturers, resulting in weaker incentives to invest in LCT. In contrast, when the unit subsidy amount μ is large (\(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{1}\)), the OSP promotes a higher CER rate. In this case, the OSP offers a larger total subsidy to manufacturers, thereby enhancing their incentives to invest in LCT.
These findings suggest that the effectiveness of TSP versus OSP in driving firms’ investment in LCT depends on the size of the unit subsidy. When the amount of subsidy per unit is low (high), manufacturers are more likely to choose to invest in a TSP (OSP).
Proposition 5. When comparing the equilibrium wholesale and retail prices under the TSP and OSP when BT is not applied, the following conclusions can be drawn: \({w}^{A* } > {w}^{B* }\), and \({p}^{A* } > {p}^{B* }\).
Proposition 5 shows that wholesale and retail prices are higher under TSP. This is because the level of total TSP is directly linked to the CER rate of manufacturers, whereas OSP is related to the total output of LC products from enterprises investing in LCT. In other words, the total amount under OSP is demand-driven; the higher the demand for LC products, the higher the production, which in turn increases the subsidy received. Therefore, manufacturers under the OSP have an incentive to lower wholesale prices, such that they can foster greater demand to increase the total subsidy. Furthermore, manufacturers under the TSP already receive subsidies when investing in LCT, which gives them an incentive to pass on costs to consumers. Consequently, manufacturers tend to set higher wholesale prices under the TSP.
These findings suggest that TSPs lead to higher wholesale and retail prices in the absence of BT. This phenomenon can be attributed to the fact that high-intensity TSP incentivises manufacturers to prioritise investments in high-value-added technologies. Such technologies often require higher product pricing to ensure cost recovery and profitability. Conversely, OSPs primarily aim to expand market scale, which intensifies price competition and constrains firms’ ability to set premium prices for their products. For example, the German government provided substantial R&D subsidies to BMW, focusing on high-value-added areas such as battery management systems, intelligent driving assistance, and vehicle connectivity (CAAM, 2024). These efforts enabled BMW to launch the i8 plug-in hybrid with a starting price significantly higher than that of comparable models, reflecting its advanced technology and premium market positioning. Excessively high product prices could discourage consumers from purchasing such products. Therefore, when BT is not applied, the government can implement an OSP to control product prices and ensure that they remain within a reasonable range.
Proposition 6. By comparing the equilibrium demand under the TSP and OSP when BT is not applied, we draw the following conclusions: when \(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{2}\), \({q}^{A* } > {q}^{B* }\); when \(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{2}\), \({q}^{B* } > {q}^{A* }\) (as shown in Fig. 3).
Proposition 6 demonstrates that when the unit subsidy amount μ is small (\(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{2}\)), the TSP is more effective in increasing demand than the OSP. When the unit subsidy amount μ is large (\(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{2}\)), the OSP is more advantageous in terms of stimulating demand. This is because, in the absence of BT, the primary factor influencing demand is the CER rate. As noted in Proposition 4, when the unit subsidy amount is small, the TSP incentivises enterprises to invest more in LCT, leading to a higher CER rate and, consequently, higher demand. In contrast, when the unit subsidy amount is larger, the main factor affecting demand is still the carbon reduction rate. However, OSP provides greater incentives for enterprises to invest in LCT, which results in higher demand.
These findings suggest that the size of the unit subsidy not only affects manufacturers’ willingness to invest in LCT under different policies, but also the quantity demanded through the CER rate. When the investment cost coefficient for LCT is high, resulting in lower investment efficiency, the level of green trust becomes a more significant factor affecting the quantity demanded than the CER rate. In such cases, enterprises can improve the green trust level of consumers through information disclosure or marketing strategies, thereby increasing demand.
Proposition 7. By comparing the equilibrium manufacturer’s and retailer’s profit under the TSP and OSP when BT is not applied, the following conclusions can be drawn: when \(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{3}\), \({\pi }_{m}^{A* } > {\pi }_{m}^{B* }\); when \(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{3}\), \({\pi }_{m}^{B* } > {\pi }_{m}^{A* }\) (as shown in Fig. 4). Further, when \(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{4}\), \({\pi }_{r}^{A* } > {\pi }_{r}^{B* }\); when \(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{4}\), \({\pi }_{r}^{B* } > {\pi }_{r}^{A* }\) (as shown in Fig. 5).
Proposition 7 demonstrates that when the unit subsidy amount μ is small (\(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{3}\) or \(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{4}\)), both manufacturers and retailers gain higher profits under the TSP. However, when the unit subsidy amount μ is large (\(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{3}\) or \(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{4}\)), the OSP is more favourable for manufacturers and retailers. According to Proposition 6, when the unit subsidy is small (large), the demand under the TSP (OSP) is higher, which in turn, helps increase the profits of SC firms.
These findings indicate that manufacturers’ and retailers’ profits are directly related to unit subsidy size. Specifically, when the unit subsidy is small (large), SC firms are more likely to choose to invest and produce under the TSP (OSP).
Proposition 8. By comparing the equilibrium CER rate under the TSP and OSP when the BT is applied, we draw the following conclusions: when \(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{5}\), \({r}^{C* } > {r}^{D* }\); when \(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{5}\), \({r}^{D* } > {r}^{C* }\) (as shown in Fig. 6).
The results show that the TSP is more effective at increasing the CER rate of enterprises under a small government subsidy for manufacturers to produce a single LC product μ (\(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{5}\)). In contrast, when the unit subsidy amount μ is large (\(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{5}\)), the OSP facilitates higher CER rates. This result mirrors the situation when BT is not applied: when the subsidy per unit is small, the TSP provides more incentives to invest in LCT, leading to a higher rate of CER. However, when the subsidy amount is larger, the OSP offers a greater incentive for manufacturers to improve their willingness to invest in LCT under the OSP, resulting in higher CER rates.
Proposition 9. By comparing the equilibrium wholesale price and the retail price under TSP and OSP when BT is applied, the following conclusions can be drawn: when \(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{6}\), \({w}^{C* } > {w}^{D* }\); when \(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{6}\), \({w}^{D* } > {w}^{C* }\) (as in Fig. 7); Further, when \(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{7}\), \({p}^{C* } > {p}^{D* }\); when \(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{7}\), \({p}^{D* } > {p}^{C* }\) (as in Fig. 8).
Proposition 9 demonstrates that when the unit subsidy μ is small (\(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{6}\) or \(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{7}\)), both wholesale and retail prices are higher under the TSP. In contrast, when the unit subsidy μ is large (\(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{6}\) or \(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{7}\)), both wholesale and retail prices are higher under the OSP. As discussed in Proposition 5, when BT is not applied, the wholesale and retail prices under the TSP are higher than those under the OSP. However, when BT is applied, the level of consumer green trust in the enterprise is maximised. Consumers can directly observe an increase in the CER rate. Consequently, the cost of LCT investment increases, prompting enterprises to pass the cost on to consumers by setting higher wholesale prices.
This analysis demonstrates that BT influences enterprise pricing strategies under different SPs. Specifically, without blockchain implementation, firms operating under TSP tend to adopt higher product pricing. Conversely, with BT adoption, firms receiving smaller total subsidies are more likely to reduce prices, reflecting a lower willingness to invest in LCT. Such firms seek to enhance profitability by leveraging price reductions, underscoring the interplay between subsidy intensity and LC investment incentives.
Proposition 10. By comparing the equilibrium demand under the TSP and OSP when BT is applied, the following conclusions can be drawn: when \(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{8}\), \({q}^{C* } > {q}^{D* }\); when \(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{8}\), \({q}^{D* } > {q}^{C* }\) (as shown in Fig. 9).
Proposition 10 shows that when the unit subsidy amount μ is small (\(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{8}\)), the TSP is more effective in increasing demand than the OSP. However, when the unit subsidy amount μ is large (\(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{8}\)), the OSP is superior for increasing demand. This result can be attributed to the fact that when enterprises apply BT, product information becomes fully transparent, and the primary factor affecting demand is the CER rate. As previously stated in Proposition 7, when the amount of unit subsidy is small (large), the CER rate under the TSP (OSP) is higher, leading to increased demand.
These findings suggest that the level of consumer green trust in enterprises is maximised when enterprises apply BT compared to when they do not. In addition, the CER rate is the primary factor influencing demand. Therefore, the government must control the application cost for BT, thereby encouraging more enterprises to adopt the technology by implementing appropriate SPs tailored to market conditions to incentivise enterprises to invest more in LCT; this can, in turn, boost demand.
Proposition 11. A comparison of the equilibrium manufacturer’s and retailer’s profits under the TSP and OSP when BT is applied leads to the following conclusion: when \(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{9}\), \({\pi }_{m}^{C* } > {\pi }_{m}^{D* }\); when \(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{9}\), \({\pi }_{m}^{D* } > {\pi }_{m}^{C* }\) (as shown in Fig. 10); Further, when \(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{10}\), \({\pi }_{r}^{C* } > {\pi }_{r}^{D* }\); when \(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{10}\), \({\pi }_{r}^{D* } > {\pi }_{r}^{C* }\) (as shown in Fig. 11).
Proposition 11 indicates that when the unit subsidy amount μ is small (\(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{9}\) or \(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{10}\)), the TSP enables SC firms to earn higher profits. Furthermore, when the unit subsidy amount μ is large (\(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{9}\) or \(\mu > {\bar{\mu }}_{10}\)), the OSP is more optimal for SC firms. According to Proposition 10, when the amount of subsidy per unit is small, the demand under the TSP is higher. Moreover, because investment in LCT is greater under the TSP, the benefits of improved production efficiency and reduced production costs are more pronounced. This leads to higher profits for SC firms. Similarly, when the unit subsidies are large, the OSP leads to higher demand and, due to increased investments in LCT, greater improvements in production efficiency and cost reductions. These factors ultimately lead to higher profits.
These findings suggest that, for SC enterprises that adopt BT, investing in LCT increases product demand, reduces production costs, and enhances production efficiency, thereby driving higher profits.
Corollary 1. The influencing factors of the policy threshold \({\bar{\mu }}_{t}\) (where \({t}=\,1,\,2,...,\,10\)) are analysed as follows:
-
(1)
\(\frac{\partial {\bar{\mu }}_{t}}{\partial z} < 0\);
-
(2)
when \(c < \bar{c}\), \(\frac{\partial {\bar{\mu }}_{6}}{\partial k} < 0\); when \(c > \bar{c}\), \(\frac{\partial {\bar{\mu }}_{6}}{\partial k} > 0\). When \(c < \widetilde{c}\), \(\frac{\partial {\bar{\mu }}_{7}}{\partial k} < 0\); when \(c > \widetilde{c}\), \(\frac{\partial {\bar{\mu }}_{7}}{\partial k} > \!\!0\);
-
(3)
\(\frac{\partial {\bar{\mu }}_{x}}{\partial k} < 0\) (where \({x}=\,1,\,2,\,3,\,4,\,5,\,8,\,9,\,10\)).
Corollary 1 (1) shows that the threshold \({\bar{\mu }}_{t}\) is negatively correlated with the initial unit production cost z. As factors such as equipment ageing reduce production efficiency, the threshold declines, thereby enhancing the effectiveness of OSP in promoting LCT adoption, consumer demand and SC performance. In contrast, for firms applying BT and making substantial LC R&D investments, improved efficiency raises \({\bar{\mu }}_{t}\), making OSP effective only under high per-unit subsidy levels—thus favouring TSP.
Corollary 1 (2) reveals that the influence of the investment cost coefficient k on thresholds \({\bar{\mu }}_{6}\) and \({\bar{\mu }}_{7}\) depends on blockchain unit cost. When blockchain cost is low (\(c < \bar{c}\) or \(c < \widetilde{c}\)), the thresholds decrease with increasing k. When the cost is high (\(c > \bar{c}\) or \(c > \widetilde{c}\)), the thresholds increase with k.
Corollary 1 (3) indicates that thresholds \({\bar{\mu }}_{x}\) are negatively related to k. This suggests that lower investment efficiency (or higher costs) reduces the threshold, making OSP a more suitable option. In high-tech firms or regions, further improvements require greater investment, lowering thresholds and enhancing the effectiveness of OSP. Conversely, higher thresholds favour TSP in low-tech settings with lower marginal investment costs.
Figure 12 further illustrates the threshold’s role in determining the effectiveness of policy. Without blockchain, a crossover point exists between TSP (Model A) and OSP (Model B). Before this point, TSP yields better outcomes. However, as k increases and \({\bar{\mu }}_{1}\) falls, OSP becomes increasingly effective at the same subsidy rate. These results suggest that policy thresholds can be adjusted through the investment cost coefficient or production cost. From an environmental standpoint, increases in either parameter lower the threshold, narrowing the scope for TSP and enhancing the relative advantage of OSP.
Key findings
The sensitivity and comparative analyses yielded several key findings.
TSP and green trust: a delicate balance between pricing and profitability
Under TSP, manufacturers’ optimal CER rate and profitability show a positive correlation with the level of green trust. In the absence of BT, product prices are higher than those under OSP. However, the adoption of BT incentivises manufacturers to increase wholesale prices, a decision directly influenced by the subsidy amount. These findings suggest that TSP trigger distinct different incentive mechanisms for manufacturers’ behaviour depending on the technological context.
Total subsidies as drivers of LC investment willingness
The study reveals that an increase in the total subsidy amount, whether provided through TSP or OSP, significantly enhances manufacturers’ willingness to invest in LCT. This finding underscores that subsidy amounts have a broad impact, influencing not only manufacturers’ specific emission reduction strategies but also acting as a vital catalyst for the overall LC transition of the SC. Therefore, the careful design of subsidy schemes is essential to ensure optimal policy outcomes.
Dual driving effect of BT and green trust
BT ensures complete transparency of LC information, thereby maximising consumer green trust. Under these circumstances, manufacturers are significantly motivated to intensify their emissions reduction efforts. Although the resulting increase in both green trust and CER rates leads to higher retail prices, the market demand for LC products continues to grow, reflecting a preference for environmentally responsible offerings. Conversely, in the absence of BT, the incomplete transparency of LC information limits green trust levels. Consequently, without active promotion and marketing of the products by governments or corporations, manufacturers must depend on further increases in CER rates and adjustments to pricing strategies to adapt to evolving consumer preferences.
Dynamic relationships between transparency and consumer demand
The study reveals that in the absence of BT, an increase in green trust effectively motivates manufacturers to intensify their emission reduction efforts. These efforts not only lead to higher wholesale and retail prices but also stimulate demand growth by strengthening consumer preferences for LC products. This finding reveals that even when information transparency is incomplete, the synergistic relationship between green trust and consumer preferences can still promote the expansion of the LC product market.
Strategic trade-offs of dual SPs
Both TSP and OSP have distinct advantages and disadvantages in terms of incentivising LC transformation. Their impacts vary significantly depending on the implementation of BT. This highlights the importance for policymakers to consider the relationship between subsidy intensity, technological transparency, and market demand when designing policies and exploring multidimensional synergies to better promote the research and application of LCT.
Numerical analysis
To demonstrate the impact of various exogenous variables on the equilibrium results of the LCSC more intuitively, numerical analysis to complement the aforementioned theoretical framework was employed. This section is divided into two parts, each focusing on the impact of the unit cost of applying BT c and consumer green trust factor λ, respectively, on the equilibrium CER rate, wholesale price, sales price, and demand and profit of SC firms.
When setting the exogenous parameters, we take solar power investment in renewable energy as an example, focusing on two major enterprises: Guodian Electric Power Development Co., Ltd. is selected as the upstream manufacturer, and State Grid Co., Ltd. is selected as the downstream retailer.
Market volume parameters
According to data from the 2023 China Renewable Energy Power Development Monitoring and Evaluation Report, released at a press conference held by the National Energy Administration of China, China’s photovoltaic power generation in 2023 will be 583.3 billion kWh (National Energy Administration, 2023). It is expected that, by 2024, China’s photovoltaic power generation will exceed 600 billion kWh; based on this, we set the market volume parameter a as a = 6 × 1011 kWh.
LCT investment cost coefficient
According to data from the 2023 Annual Report on the Cost Management of Renewable Energy Projects in China, released by the China Renewable Energy Engineering Institute, the average total investment cost of centralised photovoltaic projects is approximately 3,900 yuan/kW, representing a year-on-year decrease of approximately 8.0% (CREEI, 2023). It is expected that, by 2024, the average total investment cost of centralised photovoltaic projects will fall below 3,500 yuan/kW. Based on this, to meet the assumption requirements, we set the LCT investment cost coefficient k as \(k=0.35\times {10}^{4}{\rm{yuan}}/{\rm{kW}}\).
Unit period costs and impact factor
Based on the analysis of the period expenses of Guodian Electric Power Development Co., Ltd. before and after the launch of the blockchain platform, it is observed that the period expenses for the first three quarters of 2023 were 6.904 billion yuan, compared to 7.564 billion yuan for the same period in 2022 (China Securities Journal, 2023). Due to the inability to conduct a completely precise horizontal comparison of the influencing factors on Guodian Electric Power Development Co., Ltd.‘s period expenses between 2022 and 2023, other influences are not considered and it is assumed that the reduction in period expenses was entirely attributable to the impact of the blockchain platform. Consequently, the impact coefficient of blockchain on period expenses, denoted as η, is calculated as η = 0.91.
Furthermore, in the first three quarters of 2022, Guodian Electric Power Development Co., Ltd. generated a total of 355.03 billion kWh of electricity (Guosen Securities, 2022). By dividing the total period expenses by the total electricity generation, the unit period expense for Guodian Electric Power Development Co., Ltd. in the first three quarters of 2022 is estimated to be \(f=0.019{\rm{yuan}}/{\rm{kWh}}\).
Similarly, the total period expenses of the State Grid Corporation of China in 2022 amounted to 114.165 billion yuan, with the electricity trading volume within its operating regions reaching 4.16 trillion kWh (Baidu, 2023). Using the same method for dividing total period expenses by electricity generation, the unit period expense for the State Grid Corporation in 2022 is calculated as \(t=0.027{\rm{yuan}}/{\rm{kWh}}\).
Manufacturer’s unit cost of production
According to the report presented at the 5th China International Photovoltaic Industry Summit Forum in 2022, the cost of photovoltaic power generation in China has currently fallen to below 0.3 yuan/kWh, with an expected decrease to below 0.25 yuan/kWh during the period from 2021 to 2025 (SCOL, 2022). Based on this, we set the photovoltaic power generation cost for Guodian Electric Power Development Co., Ltd. in 2022 as z = 0.0003 × 103 yuan/kWh.
Subsidy factor of LCSPs
The TSP is based on a subsidy scheme implemented in Jing’an District, Shanghai, where a 30% investment cost subsidy is provided for self-initiated energy-saving retrofit projects (Jingan District Government, 2024). Accordingly, the subsidy ratio of TSP is set as θ = 0.3. Similarly, the OSP is informed by the subsidy scheme in Fanchang District, Wuhu City, where enterprises are granted a subsidy of 0.05 yuan/kWh for self-generated electricity after distributed photovoltaic power generation units reach 500 kW of electricity production (Fanchang District Government, 2022). Therefore, the unit subsidy amount for the OSP is set as μ = 0.00005 × 103 yuan/kWh.
Other coefficients
Referring to the study of Jabbar and Dani (2020), the unit application cost is set at c = 16.46 yuan.
To align with the assumptions established in this study, the consumer green trust coefficient is defined as λ = 0.45, the consumer LCP is specified as β = 0.6, and the efficiency coefficient of cost reduction achieved through LCT is designated as d = 0.65.
Impact of unit cost of applying BT c
The comparative static analysis results of applying BT unit cost c was presented in Figs. 13–18. In this analysis, the values of the exogenous variables were fixed as follows based on data in the literature: \(a=6\times {10}^{11}{\rm{kWh}}\), \(z=0.0003\,\times {10}^{3}\,{\rm{yuan}}/{\rm{kWh}}\), \(f=0.019\,{\rm{yuan}}/{\rm{kWh}}\), \(t=0.027\,{\rm{yuan}}/{\rm{kWh}}\), \(\beta =0.6\), \(\lambda =0.45\), \(d=0.65\), \(\theta =0.3\), \(k=0.35\,\times {10}^{4}\,{\rm{yuan}}/{\rm{kW}}\), \(\mu =0.00005\,\times {10}^{3}\,{\rm{yuan}}/{\rm{kWh}}\), and \(\eta =0.91\). The unit cost of applying BT is set as \(c\subset \left[17,27\right]{\rm{yuan}}\).
Figures 13–18 demonstrate that, as the unit cost c of applying BT increases, the CER rate, wholesale price, retail price, demand, and profits of manufacturers and retailers all decrease, irrespective of whether TSPs or OSPs are applied. The increase in the unit application cost c of blockchain implies either a reduction in the data processing efficiency of the government’s existing blockchain platform or an increase in the cost associated with constructing and maintaining the platform. Given the negative impact of rising blockchain unit application costs on these decision variables, it becomes clear that higher blockchain unit application costs hinder the sustainable development of the LC product market. This leads to reductions in the CER rate, demand, and profits of SC enterprises. To mitigate these negative effects, the government should optimise the internal structure of blockchain platforms by fostering R&D collaborations with blockchain enterprises. This can help streamline operations and improve platform efficiency. Furthermore, the government should focus on reducing the cost associated with platform construction through technological innovation and improving maintenance cost efficiency by establishing a comprehensive monitoring system. These measures reduce overall blockchain application costs, encouraging greater adoption of BT in the LC product market. When the unit subsidy amount is low (\(0 < \mu < {\bar{\mu }}_{i}\), where \(i=1,2,\ldots 10\)), the CER rate, wholesale price, retail price, demand, manufacturer’s profit, and retailer’s profit under the TSP are all greater than those under the OSP. This result verifies the conclusion of each proposition in the earlier comparative analysis section of this paper.
An analysis of Fig. 13 indicates that the impact of BT on the CER rate under both TSP and OSP is determined by the unit application cost of BT. There exists a threshold such that when the unit application cost is high (\(c > {c}_{i}\), where \(i=1,2\)), it weakens the incentive effect of LCSPs on technology investment. This aligns with the conclusion of Fan et al. (2022), which indicates that whether manufacturers adopt BT is related to its application cost. Therefore, controlling the unit application cost of BT is crucial and requires government efforts to enhance the construction and operational efficiency of blockchain systems. Figures 13–15 show that the impact of BT on information transparency directly affects firms’ pricing decisions. Although CER rates are higher under both SPs when BT is not applied (i.e., \(c > {c}_{2}\)), product prices in scenarios with blockchain applications are significantly higher than those without. This is primarily because the disclosure of LC information through blockchain incentivises consumers to “pay for” the value of LCT, motivating firms to set higher product prices. In contrast, without BT, consumers face green trust issues. Despite higher CER rates, firms setting higher prices risk significantly reducing demand, which undermines their pursuit of profit maximisation.
Figures 13 and 17 demonstrate that an increase in the unit application cost of BT leads to a decline in both the CER rate and firm profits under both TSP and OSP. This trend is primarily driven by two factors: a reduction in the market demand due to the lower CER rate and higher production costs resulting from reduced blockchain efficiency, as well as the decline in LCT levels. If firms continue investing in LCT and integrate them with production processes through blockchain platforms, production quality and efficiency can be significantly enhanced. For example, Haier Group’s COSMOPlat platform integrates LC monitoring technologies into its Qingdao air-conditioning factory, achieving a 96% early warning accuracy, a 300% increase in safety management efficiency, and effectively avoiding potential losses exceeding one million yuan (COSMOPlat, 2021). This substantially reduces production costs. Thus, the government needs to control the unit application cost of blockchain platforms to fully harness their potential for LC governance and enhance production efficiency.
Impact of the consumer green trust factor λ
The comparative static analysis results of consumer green trust factor λ is illustrated in Figs. 19–24. The values of the exogenous variables were fixed as follows, based on data in the literature: \(a=6\times {10}^{11}\,{\rm{kWh}}\), \(z=0.0003\,\times {10}^{3}\,{\rm{yuan}}/{\rm{kWh}}\), \(f=0.019\,{\rm{yuan}}/{\rm{kWh}}\), \(t=0.027\,{\rm{yuan}}/{\rm{kWh}}\), \(\beta =0.6\), \(c=16.46\,{\rm{yuan}}\), \(d=0.65\), \(\theta =0.3\), \(k=0.35\,\times {10}^{4}\,{\rm{yuan}}/{\rm{kW}}\), \(\mu =0.00005\,\times {10}^{3}\,{\rm{yuan}}/{\rm{kWh}}\), \(\eta =0.91\). To better reflect the impact of the green trust coefficient on the decision-making of enterprises and make the results more comparable, the green trust factor \(\lambda \subset \left[0.4,0.9\right]\) was set.
Figures 19–24 show that when manufacturers do not apply BT, the CER rate, wholesale price, sales price, demand, and profits of both manufacturers and retailers increase as the green trust factor λ increases under both the TSP and OSP. To further enhance the trust level, government and market regulators should introduce relevant policies. For example, they can engage third-party organisations to verify and publicly report information on whether the actual CER by enterprises aligns with their claims. Such methods can reduce the risk of greenwashing, increase transparency, and enhance consumers’ green trust. Additionally, appropriate industry associations and enterprises can collaborate to establish LC product standards with specific grades for the LC level of products within the industry. To further enhance trust, robust anti-counterfeit certification marks can be introduced to verify the authenticity of the LC information of products. In combination, these efforts can help enhance consumers’ green trust. A survey indicated that 59.7% of consumers are hesitant to purchase LC products because of their inability to recognise themFootnote 1. Therefore, improving the green trust level of enterprises is crucial for both consumers and enterprises.
As shown in Figs. 19–24, the promotion of green trust significantly enhances the incentive effect of TSP. This suggests that in cases where enterprises are not yet connected to the blockchain platform, the government can maximise the willingness of enterprises to invest in LCTs by strengthening the synergy between public relations and TSP. Increasing green trust can effectively alleviate the uncertainty regarding policy implementation and boost corporate passion for LC transformation. A real-world example is the promotion of new energy vehicles in Shanghai, China. By using an integrated online and offline publicity approach, consumers and enterprises have improved their acceptance of the policy, and the penetration rate of new energy vehicles has significantly increased. This strategy could further incentivise companies to invest in LCT. Therefore, the government should continue to strengthen social trust in green development by utilising multiple communication channels of publicity. For example, publishing successful LC project case studies and establishing authoritative certification mechanisms can increase confidence in green policies among both enterprises and the public, thereby enhancing policy effectiveness. While green trust plays a crucial role in TSP, the application of BT can further enhance the transparency and credibility of policy implementation. Therefore, the government should guide enterprises to gradually transition to blockchain platforms to leverage the advantages of LC governance.
Discussion
Government SPs are widely acknowledged as crucial tools for incentivising corporate investment in LCT and promoting energy transition. Previous research, including the work of Choi (2020), has emphasised the role of blockchain in improving SC transparency and operational efficiency. Building on this, this study introduces a government blockchain platform to investigate how TSP and OSP influence firms’ investments in LCT, their pricing strategies, and profitability.
The findings indicate that high investment cost coefficients significantly constrain firms’ willingness to invest, thereby impeding the overall LC transition of the SC. This underscores the need for firms to effectively manage capital costs and collaborate with governments and research institutions to reduce investment barriers and achieve economies of scale. Simultaneously, governments should diversify incentive structures and refine the policy environment to mitigate the adverse effects of high investment costs.
Growing consumer preferences for LC products further support firms’ green investments. Consumers’ willingness to pay a green premium not only stimulates R&D (Cai and Jiang, 2023) but also influences pricing strategies (Dong et al., 2023), enabling firms to balance cost recovery with market competitiveness. Green trust is a vital factor in this dynamic, increasing the visibility of LC products and attracting greater capital for green investments (Nguyen-Viet and Thanh Tran, 2024). The example of Bosideng’s promotion of recyclable lightweight down jackets illustrates this, as it strengthened consumer trust and expanded their market share (TMTPost, 2023).
This study also demonstrates the significant influence of SPs on firms’ investment in LCT (Li et al., 2023; Ma et al., 2021). Notably, the effectiveness of both TSP and OSP depends on the per-unit subsidy amount under OSP, irrespective of blockchain adoption. Specifically, TSPs are more effective when the unit subsidy is low, whereas OSPs provide stronger incentives when it is high. Some studies (Li et al., 2023) have suggested that TSP yields superior carbon reduction outcomes in certain sectors, such as electric vehicles (EVs). In the absence of BT, TSP may lead to increased product prices because firms potentially transfer subsidy benefits through higher wholesale prices (Li et al., 2021). Similarly, Gao et al. (2020) found that OSP can lead to price increases when consumers’ willingness to pay and income disparities are considered. From a consumer perspective, governments should carefully consider the pricing effects of TSP in environments without blockchain because price increases may discourage LC consumption. However, from a market perspective, although TSP might lead to price increases, it can stimulate investment in high-value green technologies. To reconcile the encouragement of innovation with affordability for consumers, governments could implement a combination of firm-level subsidies with consumer-side support. Although higher overall subsidies typically lead to increased profits, this contradicts the argument of Wang et al. (2021), who argued that TSP does not always maximise social welfare, whereas output subsidies consistently do. Their analysis focused on the impact of SPs on emission reduction within the context of a carbon tax, which was directly correlated with per-unit emissions and output. In contrast, OSP proves more effective in mitigating the cost burden associated with a carbon tax.
Numerical analysis further elucidates the boundaries within which subsidies are effective and demonstrates that the carbon reduction achieved through blockchain varies depending on its unit cost (Zhu et al., 2024). The proper coordination of subsidy types can enhance their overall impact. The energy crisis following the Russia-Ukraine conflict serves as a real-world illustration: under significant energy pressure, EU governments accelerated investments in renewables and energy storage. Germany’s experience, where a mix of policies, including the Renewable Energy Act (EEG) and a dedicated storage fund, led to renewable electricity surpassing 50% of total generation in 2023 (Fraunhofer ISE, 2024), demonstrating the effectiveness of coordinated subsidies. In addition, blockchain platforms enable transparent tracking of LC investments and align financial flows with policy objectives. This real-time, accurate information can reduce information asymmetry, enhance consumer trust, optimise corporate strategies, and stimulate green innovation, thereby reinforcing the effectiveness of government subsidies in driving green transformation across diverse industries.
In practical terms, government blockchain platforms improve transparency and boost consumer trust, thereby encouraging LC investment and innovation. However, high implementation costs can be a significant barrier for SMEs, particularly in emerging economies. Governments can mitigate these challenges by providing technical support and public platforms. An example is the integration of blockchain into Zhejiang’s photovoltaic industry and energy trading systems, which has effectively reduced technological disparities (SOHU, 2025), reduced investment risk, and stimulated innovation.
In summary, this study examines the impact of TSP and OSP on firms’ LC investment, using the EU’s energy response following the conflict as a relevant case study. This highlights the significance of coordinated subsidy mechanisms in advancing renewable and storage technologies and reducing reliance on fossil fuels. By leveraging blockchain platforms for transparency, governments can improve policy effectiveness and decision-making. Designing effective LCSPs requires careful consideration of subsidy types, investment costs, and industry characteristics. Integrating BT can facilitate the development of transparent governance systems that support green transformation and sustainable LC development across the industrial chain.
Conclusions
Conclusions and implications
This study offers critical insights into the synergistic effects of BT and government SPs on LCT investments, SC performance, and emission reduction outcomes. Through the integration of a game-theoretic framework with sensitivity and comparative analyses, several key findings with significant theoretical and practical implications have been revealed:
-
(1)
SP Effectiveness Depends on Funding Levels. This study demonstrates that TSPs are more effective at reducing emissions when per-unit subsidies are below industry-specific thresholds. In contrast, OSP becomes more effective when subsidy levels exceed these critical values. This threshold-dependent dynamic persists in both blockchain-integrated and conventional scenarios, although the specific threshold values vary depending on the extent of blockchain adoption. Consequently, policymakers should develop dynamic mechanisms to calibrate these thresholds, considering both industrial characteristics and blockchain implementation levels. Accordingly, enterprises should adopt differentiated operational strategies: focusing on innovative technology development under TSP regimes while emphasising production scale-up under OSP conditions. Notably, while BT moderates the influence of these thresholds, it does not eliminate them.
-
(2)
Blockchain Adoption Trade-offs. The study highlights that while blockchain enhances transparency and consumer trust, its economic viability is contingent on keeping implementation costs below certain industry-specific thresholds. Consequently, firms should strategically prioritise the deployment of blockchain solutions in markets where trust levels are low and the costs associated with verification can be effectively managed. To encourage broader adoption, Policymakers should focus on establishing infrastructure standards and deploying public validation nodes, thereby lowering barriers to business implementation.
-
(3)
Consumer Influence on Policy Effectiveness. Strong consumer preference for green products enhances the synergistic effect of BT and government subsidies. However, in mature markets where consumer trust in green products is already high, the marginal benefits of blockchain adoption may not justify the associated costs. Therefore, firms should carefully assess market-specific trust levels before investing in BT. Policymakers, on the other hand, should complement SPs with consumer education to maximise the overall impact of their LC strategies.
-
(4)
SC Dynamics Across Subsidies. TSPs tend to favour firms focused on innovation by allowing for premium pricing, whereas OSPs are more advantageous for operations prioritising scale. The integration of BT enhances SC coordination by enabling real-time verification of LC claims, facilitating more synchronised pricing and production decisions. Therefore, firms should tailor their strategies based on dominant subsidy types in their operating environment while also leveraging blockchain for cross-functional integration and information transparency across the SC.
Contributions
This study advances the literature on LC transition mechanisms by developing a novel analytical framework that bridges previously disconnected research streams. Unlike existing studies that investigate blockchain applications in SCs or subsidy effects in isolation, this study’s integrated approach systematically combines blockchain-enabled traceability systems, government subsidy mechanisms and consumer behavioural responses to reveal their synergistic impacts on corporate LC investment strategies. By modelling these triadic interactions, the framework offers a more comprehensive understanding of how technological, policy and market factors jointly influence sustainable production transitions. The findings provide actionable guidance for multiple stakeholders: enterprises can leverage these insights to align investment strategies with policy types and market conditions, while policymakers are advised to establish policy-technology matching databases to enable the dynamic adjustment of subsidy mechanisms and blockchain support, with a particular focus on implementing tailored policy mixes within high-emission industries, such as power generation, steel, and chemicals, to maximise emission reduction benefits. The study’s dual theoretical and practical innovations offer a scalable solution for accelerating the LC transition.
Future work
This study’s investigation of government LCSPs and BT on firms’ LCT investment strategies identifies several promising areas for future research. First, subsequent studies should further explore the applications of blockchain in SCs. This includes investigating the potential risks of information leakage in blockchain-enabled SCs and analysing consumer attitudes towards BT and their role within SC ecosystems. In addition, the automatic execution characteristics of blockchain smart contracts and the decentralised architecture have disrupted the traditional power dynamics between governments and enterprises. Future research can focus closely on these two characteristics to deeply analyse how they trigger the structural transformation of the game relationship between governments and enterprises. Second, it is imperative to extend existing research through the development of dynamic modelling approaches, such as multi-period or evolutionary game models, to capture the dynamic adjustment processes of LCT investment and pricing strategies. Furthermore, future research should leverage blockchain’s real-time data capabilities to design dynamic subsidy mechanisms that can adapt to evolving market conditions. Third, future research should integrate blockchain investment decisions into analytical frameworks. This includes modelling endogenous blockchain adoption decisions by governments and firms and quantifying the economic returns generated by blockchain platforms in facilitating LCT investments. Fourth, it is equally essential for future research to examine policy effectiveness under conditions of information asymmetry. This involves analysing how asymmetrical information moderates the impacts of SPs and BT and how firms adjust their strategic behaviours across different information structures. Additionally, expanding the analysis to competitive environments involving multiple or bilateral markets can enhance the generalisability and applicability of policy recommendations. Cross-industry comparative studies and investigations into bilateral market structures are particularly valuable for refining policy design and ensuring applicability across diverse economic contexts. Finally, future research should critically focus on optimising the combination of various policy instruments. This involves exploring the potential synergistic effects between blockchain and CAT mechanisms, as well as developing specifically targeted subsidy programmes for blockchain-enabled LCT initiatives.
These research directions will advance the understanding of the synergistic mechanisms between BT and policy interventions, offering actionable insights for both policymakers and enterprises. Notably, the development of dynamic modelling frameworks and cross-market comparative analyses will enhance the practical relevance of research findings across diverse economic contexts, thereby enabling more precise and effective policy support for LC transitions.
Data availability
Data sharing is not applicable to this research as no data were generated or analysed. Reason: This article only involves mathematical derivation, and the picture part of numerical analysis is completed using Excel, and does not involve the data that needs to be uploaded.
References
Abdelgalil T, Manolas V, Maglaras L, Kantzavelou I, Ferrag MA (2021) Blockchain technology: a case study in supply chain management. 2021 Third IEEE international conference on trust, privacy and security in intelligent systems and applications (TPS-ISA). IEEE. pp. 331–339
Alqarni MA, Alkatheiri MS, Chauhdary SH, Saleem S (2023) Use of blockchain-based smart contracts in logistics and supply chains. Electronics 12(6):1340
Ameyaw EE, Edwards DJ, Kumar B, Thurairajah N, Owusu-Manu DG, Oppong GD (2023) Critical factors influencing adoption of blockchain-enabled smart contracts in construction projects. J Constr Eng M 149(3):04023003
Babaei A, Tirkolaee E, Boz E (2025) Optimizing energy consumption for blockchain adoption through renewable energy sources. Renew Energ 238:121936
Babich V, Hilary G (2020) Distributed ledgers and operations: what operations management researchers should know about blockchain technology. M&SOM-Manuf Serv Oper Manag 22(2):223–240. https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2018.0752
Bai R, Lin B, Liu X (2021) Government subsidies and firm-level renewable energy investment: new evidence from partially linear functional-coefficient models. Energ Policy 159:112610
Baidu (2023) National Energy Administration: New Installed Capacity of Wind and Photovoltaic Power in 2022 Exceeds 100 Million kW for Three Consecutive Years, Reaching 125 Million kW. https://baijiahao.baidu.com/s?id=1757707106944671209&wfr=spider&for=pc. Accessed 13 Feb 2023
Bian J, Zhang G, Zhou G (2020) Manufacturer vs. consumer subsidy with green technology investment and environmental concern. Eur J Oper Res 287(3):832–843
Cai J, Jiang F (2023) Decision models of pricing and carbon emission reduction for low-carbon supply chain under cap-and-trade regulation. Int J Prod Econ 264:108964
China Renewable Energy Engineering Institute (CREEI) (2023) China renewable energy project cost management report 2023. http://www.creei.cn/web/content.html?id=6461. Accessed 28 Jun 2024
Chen W, Ma Y, Bai C (2021) The impact of carbon emission quota allocation regulations on the investment of low-carbon technology in electric power industry under peak-valley price policy. IEEE T Eng Manage 71:374–391
Chen Z, Zhang Y, Wang H, Ouyang X, Xie Y (2022) Can green credit policy promote low-carbon technology innovation? J Clean Prod 359:132061
China Securities Journal (2023) Guodian Electric Power: Net profit of 5.624 billion yuan in the first three quarters of 2023, a year-on-year increase of 12.88%. https://www.sohu.com/a/731669546_120988533. Accessed 27 Oct 2023
China Huadian Corporation (CHD) (2023) China Huadian: implement the dual-carbon strategy and firmly take the road of green development. http://www.sasac.gov.cn/n4470048/n26915116/n28283133/n28283138/c28337662/content.html. Accessed 7 Jul 2023
China Association of Automobile Manufacturers (CAAM) (2024) The German government plans to subsidize research and development of electric car batteries. http://www.caam.org.cn/item/tags-jee%25252525252525252525252520p%D7%D4%D3%C9%B9%E2/chn/9/cate_106/con_5222066.html. Accessed 20 Mar 2019
Choi T, Feng L, Li R (2020) Information disclosure structure in supply chains with rental service platforms in the blockchain technology era. Int J Prod Econ 221:107473
China National Radio (CNR) News (2022) Shenzhen Ecological Environment Bureau and Tencent completed the first personal carbon inclusive emission reduction transaction carbon reduction 12 kg can be exchanged for travel vouchers. https://baijiahao.baidu.com/s?id=1752011596453091408&wfr=spider&for=pc. Accessed 12 Dec 2022
Chuah S, El-Manstrly D, Tseng M, Ramayah T (2020) Sustaining customer engagement behavior through corporate social responsibility: The roles of environmental concern and green trust. J Clean Prod 262:121348
COSMOPlat (2021) The Smart Safety Management and Control of a Central Air Conditioning Factory in Qingdao. https://www.cosmoplat.com/case?id=1466282944313827329. Accessed 1 Jul 2021
Deng Y, You D, Zhang Y (2021) Research on improvement strategies for low-carbon technology innovation based on a differential game: The perspective of tax competition. Sustain Prod Consump 26:1046–1061
Deng LR, Ying Z, Ling T (2024) Research on low-carbon dual-channel supply chain emission reduction and financing strategy based on blockchain. IEEE Access
DOIT (2024) Quchain technology pollution reduction and carbon reduction synergistic platform won the “2023 China’s New Smart City Typical Case Collection”. https://www.doit.com.cn/p/507472.html. Accessed 8 Jan 2024
Dolgui A, Ivanov D, Potryasaev S, Sokolov B, Ivanova M, Werner F (2020) Blockchain-oriented dynamic modelling of smart contract design and execution in the supply chain. Int J Prod Res 58(7):2184–2199
Dong CW, Huang QZ, Fan DB (2023) Channel selection and pricing strategy with supply chain finance and blockchain. Int J Prod Econ 265. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2023.109006
Dong G, Liang L, Wei L, Xie J, Yang G (2023) Optimization model of trade credit and asset-based securitization financing in carbon emission reduction supply chain. Ann Oper Res 331:35–84
Du Y, Wang Z, Li J, Shi L, Jayakody DNK, Chen Q, Han Z (2022) Blockchain-aided edge computing market: smart contract and consensus mechanisms. IEEE T Mobile Comput 22(6):3193–3208
Energy and Power (EP) (2023) Record 9.6% Growth in Renewables Achieved Despite Energy Crisis. https://ep-bd.com/view/details/news/MjY1OA==/title?q=Record+9.6%25+Growth+in+Renewables+Achieved+Despite+Energy+Crisis. Accessed 21 Mar 2023
Fan ZP, Wu XY, Cao BB (2022) Considering the traceability awareness of consumers: should the supply chain adopt the blockchain technology. Ann Oper Res 309(2):837–860. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-020-03729-y
Feng Z, Luo N, Shalpegin T, Cui H (2024) The influence of carbon emission reduction instruments on blockchain technology adoption in recycling batteries of the new energy vehicles. Int J Prod Res 62(3):891–908
Fragkos P, van Soest HL, Schaeffer R, Reedman L, Köberle AC, Macaluso N, Iyer G (2021) Energy system transitions and low-carbon pathways in Australia, Brazil, Canada, China, EU-28, India, Indonesia, Japan, Republic of Korea, Russia and the United States. Energy 216:119385
Fraunhofer ISE (2024) Öffentliche Stromerzeugung 2024: Deutscher Strommix so sauber wie nie. https://energy-charts.info/?l=de&c=DE. Accessed 2 Jan 2025
Gao L, Hiruta Y, Ashina S (2020) Promoting renewable energy through the willingness to pay for the transition to a low carbon society in Japan. Renew Energ 162:818–830
Green Building Advisor (GBA) (2017) Energy Star brings significant benefits to America: why put it at risk? https://m.etiketa4.com/article/energy-star-delivers-big-for-america-why-put-it-at-risk. Accessed 20 Apr 2017
Guo S, Sun X, Lam HK (2020) Applications of blockchain technology in sustainable fashion supply chains: operational transparency and environmental efforts. IEEE T Eng Manage 70(4):1312–1328
Guo Y, Bai C, Lev B (2024) Independence or cooperation? Evaluating emission reduction strategies in non-competitive and competitive environments. J Oper Res Soc 76:659–676
Guosen Securities (2022) Guodian Electric Power (600795.SH) reports significant increase in net profit and notable improvement in profitability. https://pdf.dfcfw.com/pdf/H3_AP202211141580222516_1.pdf?1668431245000.pdf=. Accessed 26 Oct 2022
Hasan MR, Roy TC, Daryanto Y, Wee HM (2021) Optimizing inventory level and technology investment under a carbon tax, cap-and-trade and strict carbon limit regulations. Sustain Prod Consump 25:604–621
He J, Li Z, Zhang X, Wang H, Dong W, Du E, Zhang D (2022) Towards carbon neutrality: a study on China’s long-term low-carbon transition pathways and strategies. Environ Sci Ecotechnol 9:100134
He L, Wang H, Liu F (2024) Emission abatement in low-carbon supply chains with government subsidy and information asymmetry. Int J Prod Res 62(18):6598–6626
Hua W, Jiang J, Sun H, Teng F, Strbac G (2022) Consumer-centric decarbonization framework using Stackelberg game and Blockchain. Appl Energ 309:118384
i SHANDONG (2024) Weifang’s “blockchain +“ vegetable project was selected into the list of outstanding projects of the Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Affairs. https://sdxw.iqilu.com/share/YS0yMS0xNTI5MTEzOA==.html. Accessed 5 Jan 2024
Jabbar A, Dani S (2020) Investigating the link between transaction and computational costs in a blockchain environment. Int J Prod Res 58(11):3423–3436
Ji GJ, Zhou S, Lai KH, Kumar A, Tan KH (2022) Timing of blockchain adoption in a supply chain with competing manufacturers. Int J Prod Econ 247. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2022.108430
Jiang R, Kang YJ, Liu YS, Liang ZH, Duan YL, Sun YN, Liu JL (2022) A trust transitivity model of small and medium-sized manufacturing enterprises under blockchain-based supply chain finance. Int J Prod Econ 247:108469
Kang Y, Dong P, Ju Y, Zhang T (2024) Differential game theoretic analysis of the blockchain technology investment and carbon reduction strategy in digital supply chain with government intervention. Comput Ind Eng 189:109953
Li B, Geng Y, Xia X, Qiao D (2021) The impact of government subsidies on the low-carbon supply chain based on carbon emission reduction level. Int J Env Res Pub Health 18(14):7603
Li F, Xu X, Li Z, Du P, Ye J (2021) Can low-carbon technological innovation truly improve enterprise performance? The case of Chinese manufacturing companies. J Clean Prod 293:125949
Li G, Yang L, Zhang B, Li X, Chen F (2021) How do environmental values impact green product purchase intention? The moderating role of green trust. Environ Sci Pollut R 28:46020–46034
Li Y, Liao A, Li L, Zhang M, Zhao X, Ye F (2023) Reinforcing or weakening? The role of blockchain technology in the link between consumer trust and organic food adoption. J Bus Res 164:113999
Li YN, Liang C, Ye F, Zhao X (2023) Designing government subsidy schemes to promote the electric vehicle industry: A system dynamics model perspective. Transport Res A-Pol 167:103558
Li ZD, Zheng C, Liu A, Yang Y, Yuan X (2022) Environmental taxes, green subsidies, and cleaner production willingness: Evidence from China’s publicly traded companies. Technol Forecast Soc 183:121906
Li YN, Tong Y, Ye F, Song J (2020) The choice of the government green subsidy scheme: Innovation subsidy vs. product subsidy. Int J Prod Res 58(16):4932–4946
Li ZM, Pan YC, Yang W, Ma JH, Zhou M (2021) Effects of government subsidies on green technology investment and green marketing coordination of supply chain under the cap-and-trade mechanism. Energy Econ 101. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2021.105426
Liu L, Wang Z, Li X, Liu Y, Zhang Z (2022) An evolutionary analysis of low-carbon technology investment strategies based on the manufacturer-supplier matching game under government regulations. Environ Sci Pollut R 29(29):44597–44617
Liu Z, Sun H (2021) Assessing the impact of emissions trading scheme on low-carbon technological innovation: Evidence from China. Environ Impact Asses 89:106589
Lyu R, Zhang C, Li Z, Li Y (2022) Manufacturers’ integrated strategies for emission reduction and recycling: The role of government regulations. Comput Ind Eng 163:107769
Lyu HY, Ma C, Arash F (2024) Government innovation subsidies, green technology innovation and carbon intensity of industrial firms. J Environ Manage 369:122274
Ma SG, He Y, Gu R, Li, SS (2021) Sustainable supply chain management considering technology investments and government intervention. Transp Res Pt e-Logist Transp Rev 149. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tre.2021.102290
Ma D, Zhu Q (2022) Innovation in emerging economies: research on the digital economy driving high-quality green development. J Bus Res 145:801–813
Manupati VK, Schoenherr T, Ramkumar M, Wagner SM, Pabba SK, Inder Raj Singh RJ (2020) A blockchain-based approach for a multi-echelon sustainable supply chain. Int J Prod Res 58(7):2222–2241
Natanelov V, Cao S, Foth M, Dulleck U (2022) Blockchain smart contracts for supply chain finance: mapping the innovation potential in Australia-China beef supply chains. J Ind Inf Integr 30:100389
National Energy Administration (2023) Notice of the National Energy Administration on the issuance of 2023 National Renewable Energy Power Development Monitoring and Evaluation Results. https://zfxxgk.nea.gov.cn/2024-10/10/c_1310787115.htm. Accessed 10 Oct 2024
Nguyen-Viet B, Thanh Tran C (2024) Sustaining organizational customers’ consumption through corporate social responsibility and green advertising receptivity: the mediating role of green trust. Cogent Bus Manag 11(1):2287775
Niu BZ, Shen ZF, Xie FF (2021) The value of blockchain and agricultural supply chain parties’ participation confronting random bacteria pollution. J Clean Prod 319. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.128579
Parmentola A, Petrillo A, Tutore I, De Felice F (2022) Is blockchain able to enhance environmental sustainability? A systematic review and research agenda from the perspective of Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs). Bus Strateg Environ 31(1):194–217
PR Newswire (2017) Bitfury Expands Blockchain Land Ownership Registration Project with the Government of Georgia. https://www.prnasia.com/story/169586-1.shtml. Accessed 9 Feb 2017
Pun H, Swaminathan JM, Hou P(2021) Blockchain Adoption for Combating Deceptive Counterfeits. Prod Oper Manag 30:864–882
Rahman MM, Sultana N, Velayutham E (2022) Renewable energy, energy intensity and carbon reduction: Experience of large emerging economies. Renew Energ 184:252–265
Sichuan Online (SCOL) (2022) Power generation costs reduced to less than 0.3 yuan per kWh: How can photovoltaic power address the issue of instability? https://sichuan.scol.com.cn/ggxw/202208/58596511.html. Accessed 29 Aug 2022
Shandong big data Bureau (2024) Hanting District, Weifang City: “blockchain + vegetables” to create a worry-free agricultural product traceability journey. http://bdb.shandong.gov.cn/art/2024/5/6/art_79176_10327365.html. Accessed 6 May 2024
Shang WL, Lv Z (2023) Low carbon technology for carbon neutrality in sustainable cities: a survey. Sustain Cities Soc 92:104489
Shanghai Jing’an District People’s Government (Jingan District) (2024) Jing‘an District 2024 Enterprise energy saving, emission reduction and carbon reduction support fund declaration guide. https://www.jingan.gov.cn/govxxgk/JA2/2024-04-26/f91aa2a0-863b-4085-a826-a3a4f814b926.html?type=2. Accessed 26 Apr 2024
SOHU (2025) The new patent of Zhejiang Power Trading Center will improve the efficiency of comprehensive energy trading, and the blockchain will help the future. https://www.sohu.com/a/858602668_122066678. Accessed 13 Feb 2025
Sun LC, Cao XX, Alharthi M, Zhang JJ, Taghizadeh-Hesary F, Mohsin M (2020) Carbon emission transfer strategies in supply chain with lag time of emission reduction technologies and low-carbon preference of consumers. J Clean Prod 264. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.121664
Sun Y, Hu H, Jin G (2022) Pollution or innovation? How enterprises react to air pollution under perfect information. Sci Total Environ 831:154821
Song YZ, Li Y, Liu TS (2023) Carbon asset remolding and potential benefit measurement of machinery products in the light of lean production and low-carbon investment. Technol Forecast Soc Chang 186. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2022.122166
TMTPost (2023) The “Double 11” has come to an end! Bosideng topped the sales list of clothing brands on Tmall, sending its shares up more than 6%. https://www.toutiao.com/article/7300884625155506722. Accessed 13 Nov 2023
Wang H, Wei W (2020) Coordinating technological progress and environmental regulation in CO2 mitigation: the optimal levels for OECD countries & emerging economies. Energ Econ 87:104510
Wang YL, Chen CH, Zghari-Sales A (2020) Designing a blockchain enabled supply chain. Int J Prod Res 59(5):1450–1475. https://doi.org/10.1080/00207543.2020.1824086
Wang W, Wang Y, Zhang X, Zhang D (2021) Effects of government subsidies on production and emissions reduction decisions under carbon tax regulation and consumer low-carbon awareness. Int J Env Res Pub Health 18(20):10959
Wang Q, Xiu X, Ji X, Zhao N (2024) Joint decisions on selling mode choice and emission reduction investment under cap-and-trade regulation. Int J Prod Res 62(18):6753–6780
Wuhu Fanchang District People’s Government (Fanchang District) (2022) Notice of Fanchang District People’s Government Office on issuing several support measures for energy conservation and carbon reduction in Fanchang District. https://www.fanchang.gov.cn/openness/public/6604641/33869351.html. Accessed 9 Mar 2022
Xu XP, Zhang MY, Dou GW, Yu YG (2021) Coordination of a supply chain with an online platform considering green technology in the blockchain era. Int J Prod Res 61(11):3793–3810. https://doi.org/10.1080/00207543.2021.1894367
Xu J, Duan YR (2022) Pricing and greenness investment for green products with government subsidies: when to apply blockchain technology. Electron Commer Res Appl 51. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.elerap.2021.101108
Yang G, Nie Y, Li H, Wang H (2023) Digital transformation and low-carbon technology innovation in manufacturing firms: the mediating role of dynamic capabilities. Int J Prod Econ 263:108969
Zhong YG, Yang T, Yu HL, Zhong S, Xie W (2023) Impacts of blockchain technology with government subsidies on a dual-channel supply chain for tracing product information. Transp Res Pt e-Logist Transp Rev 171. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tre.2023.103032
Zhu C, Lee CC (2022) The effects of low-carbon pilot policy on technological innovation: evidence from prefecture-level data in China. Technol Forecast Soc 183:121955
Zhu J, Feng T, Lu Y, Jiang W (2024) Using blockchain or not? A focal firm’s blockchain strategy in the context of carbon emission reduction technology innovation. Bus Strateg Environ 33(4):3505–3531
Acknowledgements
The research was supported by China Postdoctoral Science Foundation (2023M740532); Interdisciplinary Innovation Team Programme of Chengdu University of Technology under Grant (25JCXK09); Philosophy and Social Science Research Fund of Chengdu University of Technology (YJ2024-QN002); Chengdu High Quality Development Research Centre Project (yb2023104); Chengdu Park City Demonstration Zone Construction Research Centre (GYCS2024-ZD001).
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Contributions
Wei Chen: conceptualisation, methodology, writing—review & editing, supervision, funding acquisition. Yuankun Chen: software, validation, formal analysis, investigation, writing—original draft preparation. Xin Huang: writing—review & editing, visualisation.
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Competing interests
The authors declare no competing interests.
Ethical approval
Ethical approval was not required as the study did not involve human participants.
Informed consent
This article does not contain any studies with human participants performed by any of the authors.
Additional information
Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Supplementary information
Rights and permissions
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International License, which permits any non-commercial use, sharing, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if you modified the licensed material. You do not have permission under this licence to share adapted material derived from this article or parts of it. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/.
About this article
Cite this article
Wei, C., Yuankun, C. & Xin, H. Low-carbon technology investment strategies with blockchain under subsidy policies. Humanit Soc Sci Commun 12, 1459 (2025). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41599-025-05590-5
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41599-025-05590-5